Ex Parte 7,418,423 et alDownload PDFPatent Trial and Appeal BoardNov 14, 201395000432 (P.T.A.B. Nov. 14, 2013) Copy Citation UNITED STATES PATENT AND TRADEMARK OFFICE UNITED STATES DEPARTMENT OF COMMERCE United States Patent and Trademark Office Address: COMMISSIONER FOR PATENTS P.O. Box 1450 Alexandria, Virginia 22313-1450 www.uspto.gov APPLICATION NO. FILING DATE FIRST NAMED INVENTOR ATTORNEY DOCKET NO. CONFIRMATION NO. 95/000,432 07/29/2009 7,418,423 00013-00002US4 3919 38662 7590 11/14/2013 LAW OFFICES OF GRADY L. WHITE, LLC 10605 Concord Street , SUITE 207 Kensington, MD 20895 EXAMINER RIMELL, SAMUEL G ART UNIT PAPER NUMBER 3992 MAIL DATE DELIVERY MODE 11/14/2013 PAPER Please find below and/or attached an Office communication concerning this application or proceeding. The time period for reply, if any, is set in the attached communication. PTOL-90A (Rev. 04/07) UNITED STATES PATENT AND TRADEMARK OFFICE ____________________ BEFORE THE PATENT TRIAL AND APPEAL BOARD ____________________ TELVENT DTN, LLC Requester, Cross-Appellant, Respondent v. FARMS TECHNOLOGY, LLC Patent Owner, Appellant, Respondent ____________________ Appeal 2013-007499 Inter partes Reexamination 95/000,432 Patent US 7,418,423 B2 Technology Center 3900 ____________________ Before HOWARD B. BLANKENSHIP, MEREDITH C. PETRAVICK, and WILLIAM V. SAINDON, Administrative Patent Judges. SAINDON, Administrative Patent Judge. DECISION ON APPEAL Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 2 STATEMENT OF THE CASE Claims 1-29 are rejected and are the subject of the present appeal. Patent Owner appeals under 35 U.S.C. §§ 134(b) and 315(a) (2002) and Requester cross-appeals under §§ 134(c) and 315(b). We have jurisdiction under 35 U.S.C. § 134. We held an Oral Hearing with representatives of both parties present on September 25, 2013. We REVERSE the Examiner‟s decision to reject the claims using certain rejections in the appeal and AFFIRM the Examiner‟s decision not to adopt certain rejections in the cross-appeal. We enter a NEW GROUND of rejection for all claims. The Claimed Subject Matter The disclosed invention relates to a method for automated commodities trading system with an automatic hedging function. Corn is an exemplary commodity. A producer of corn (a farmer) typically can either sell to or rent space from a grain elevator, which stores and maintains the corn. From the perspective of the elevator operator, the purchase of corn is risky because the operator could purchase the corn from a producer at a fair market price on day 1 and then on day 2 the price for corn could drop. ‟423 patent col. 2:24-31. The price on day 2 could fall enough such that the elevator operator would not be able to cover the costs associated with storage and transport to market, let alone make a profit (all of these factors are called the “basis”). Id. at col. 2:12-14. Accordingly, the elevator operator does two things. One, the operator offers to purchase the corn at a rate of the market prices less its basis. Id. at col. 2:14-20. Two, at the same Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 3 time, the operator purchases a hedge order to sell the corn at that market price at some time in the future, thus preserving the margin. Id. at col. 2:32- 59. The disclosed invention provides an automatic system for elevator operators to enact this hedging strategy. Claim 1, reproduced below, is exemplary: 1. A method for executing a commodities transaction on a net market system, said method comprising: (a) receiving on the net market system bid information for a plurality of buyers of a commodity, the bid information including for each buyer in the plurality of buyers a buyer- specific basis for the commodity; (b) storing the bid information on the net market system; (c) repetitively receiving an updated commodity exchange price for the commodity and calculating for each buyer in the plurality of buyers a buyer-specific flat price based on the buyer-specific basis for said each buyer and said updated commodity exchange price; (d) receiving an offer from a seller to sell an offered quantity of the commodity to at least one buyer in the plurality of buyers at the buyer-specific flat price for said at least one buyer; (e) responsive to receiving the offer, attempting to secure a futures contract for the commodity on behalf of said at least one buyer based on the offer; and (f) if the attempt to secure the futures contract succeeds, generating a contract between said at least one buyer and the seller based on the offer; (g) wherein steps (c) through (f) are carried out automatically by the net market system without intervention from said at least one buyer. Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 4 Rejections & Evidence The rejections on appeal and cross-appeal rely on the following evidence: Lindsey et al. (“Lindsey”) US 5,063,507 Nov. 5, 1991 Marynowski et al. (“Marynowski”) US 2006/0259417 A1 Nov. 16, 2006 Barbara L. Schlei, “Electronic Trading of Agricultural Products” (USDA 1980) (“ETAP”). L.A. Times Financial Desk, “Ins and Outs of Program Trading, and Why It‟s Being Blamed for Market Collapse,” L.A. Times, Business, p. 14 (Dec. 6, 1987) (“LA Times”). Philip Crawford, “The New High-Tech Investing: Computer as Fund Manager,” International Herald Tribune (Feb. 1, 1992) (“Herald Tribune”). Chicago Board of Trade, “Commodity Trading Manual” (1998) (“CTM”). Brian D. Adam et al., “Storage Hedging: What‟s a Merchandiser to Do?,” Proceedings of the NCR-134 Conference on Applied Commodity Price Analysis, Forecasting, and Market Risk Management (1993). Terry L. Kastens and Kevin C. Dhuyvetter, “Post-Harvest Grain Storing and Hedging with Efficient Futures,” J. Ag. Res. Econ. 24(2):482-505 (1999). New York Mercantile Exchange, “A Guide to Energy Hedging” (1999) (“Guide to Energy Hedging”). Appeal The following rejections under 35 U.S.C. §§ 102 and 103 are on appeal (App. Br. PO 10-11): I. Claims 1 and 16 as anticipated by Lindsey. RAN 12 (incorporating First Office Action, mailed May 28, 2010 (“FOA”), at 12-14). Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 5 II. Claims 1-29 as unpatentable over LA Times, Herald Tribune, and Kastens. RAN 21-23 (incorporating Exhibit 44a). III. Claims 1-29 as unpatentable over LA Times, CTM, and Lindsey. RAN 29-30 (incorporating Exhibit 47a). IV. Claims 1-29 as unpatentable over Herald Tribune, CTM, and Lindsey. RAN 31-32 (incorporating Exhibit 48a). V. Claims 1-29 as unpatentable over LA Times, Guide to Energy Hedging, and Lindsey. RAN 40-42 (incorporating Exhibit 53a). VI. Claims 1-29 as unpatentable over Herald Tribune, Guide to Energy Hedging, and Lindsey. RAN 42-43 (incorporating Exhibit 54a). Cross-Appeal The following non-adopted rejections under 35 U.S.C. § 103 are on cross-appeal (App. Br. Req. 8-9): VII. Claims 1-29 as unpatentable over LA Times, Herald Tribune, and CTM. RAN 6-8. VIII. Claims 1-29 as unpatentable over LA Times, CTM, and ETAP. RAN 25-27. IX. Claims 1-29 as unpatentable over LA Times, CTM, and Marynowski. RAN 32-34. X. Claims 1-29 as unpatentable over Herald Tribune, CTM, and Marynowski. RAN 34-36. XI. Claims 1-29 as unpatentable over LA Times, Herald Tribune, and Adam. RAN 20-21. OPINION Patent Owner‟s Appeal Independent claim 1 requires, in pertinent part, a step of calculating a buyer-specific flat price based on the buyer-specific basis and an updated commodity exchange price. Independent claim 16 requires a similar Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 6 limitation, such that our analysis for claim 1 will be applicable to claim 16. The resolution of this appeal turns on the Examiner‟s interpretation of this claim limitation and subsequent reading of the claim limitation on the references. See, e.g., App. Br. PO 12. Patent Owner‟s appeal apprises us of error in the Examiner‟s rejections regarding the reading of a step of calculating a “buyer-specific flat price” using a “buyer-specific basis” on certain features of Lindsey and Kastens. “Buyer-Specific Basis” The Examiner first determines that “buyer specific basis” means “the actions of the grain elevator operator who determines overhead costs as a consideration when submitting a bid for a grain commodity.” RAN 81. The Examiner then determines that the broadest reasonable interpretation of the term is “to refer to the overhead costs for any type of commodity buyer.” Id. (emphasis removed). This interpretation of “buyer-specific basis” is only partially correct. As the ‟423 patent clearly states, “[t]he basis includes the elevator‟s costs, such as transportation to market and costs associated with running the facilities, as well as the margin.” ‟423 patent col. 2:12-14 (emphasis added). Accordingly, basis is costs plus margin. By including a fixed margin, the buyer seeks to eliminate some of the risk of market variability. In view of the above, we construe a “buyer specific basis” to include the costs plus margin for the buyer. See also App. Br. PO 20. Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 7 Analysis of the Examiner’s Findings Regarding Lindsey In application, the Examiner reads “buyer specific basis” on certain features of the Loan Advance Program (LAP) in Lindsey. RAN 81 (citing Lindsey, col. 19:43-62). The LAP offers the producer a cash advance equal to a government guarantee and the producer sets a net equity per bale desired. Lindsey, col. 19:34-37, 43-45. The TELCOT 1 system in Lindsey then “calculates the loan amount and all charges such as storage and interest in order to offer the cotton at a price to buyers so that the producer nets the desired amount of equity per-bale.” Id. at 19:45-48. This calculation is updated every night. Id. at 19:48-62. In view of this passage, we find that Lindsey calculates an offer to sell price based on cash advanced, desired equity, storage, and interest. What we do not find is an offer to buy price, a commodity exchange price, the buyer‟s costs, or the buyer‟s margin. The Examiner reasons that bids made in response to the offer to sell price “will include the storage and interest costs . . . because those costs are recovered by the seller from the buyer.” RAN 81 (emphasis removed). However, the Examiner does not address how this satisfies the limitation of claim 1 requiring a calculation of a buyer-specific flat price based on a received updated commodity exchange price nor does it address the requirement to receive buyer-specific basis information. The Examiner then goes on to say that the exchange prices are discussed in Lindsey in the “Monitor Summary Function,” which “functions like a conventional stock ticker tape.” RAN 81-82 (citing Lindsey, col. 1 TELCOT is “a computer-based electronic marketing system . . . with functions much like those available to NYSE or AMEX traders.” Lindsey, col. 14:64-67. Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 8 20:37-40). However, the data from the Monitor Summary Function is not used in the LAP calculation upon which the Examiner bases the rejection. Just because update commodity exchange data exists somewhere in the TELCOT system does not mean that it is used in the LAP calculation. Finally, the Examiner finds that the offer to sell price by TELCOT in the LAP “becomes the „buyer specific flat price‟ because it is the price offered to the buyer . . . that takes into account the overhead charges.” RAN 82. This finding is erroneous because a price offered by a seller that takes into account a seller‟s overhead charges is different from a price offered by a buyer that takes into account a buyer‟s overhead charges. An offer to buy is different from an offer to sell. Likewise, a buyer‟s overhead is different from a seller‟s overhead. Thus, calculations of buyer‟s prices are different from calculations of seller‟s prices. Even if the prices end up at the same value, the way in which they are reached is different because they take into consideration different costs and considerations of different parties. In view of the above, Patent Owner‟s arguments apprise us of an error in the Examiner‟s finding that Lindsey discloses the use of an updated commodity exchange price to repeatedly calculate a buyer-specific flat price, as well as in improperly construing, and reading on Lindsey, a “buyer- specific basis.” See App. Br. PO 16-22. Analysis of Requester’s Response Regarding Lindsey Requester‟s comments do not persuade us to the contrary. Requester points out that updated commodity exchange price information and a buyer- specific basis “were clearly available to the Lindsey computer.” Resp. Br. Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 9 Req. 8. However, even if the data were available, that does not mean that each feature of TELCOT uses that particular data. Requester next points to a “limit price” feature of TELCOT‟s Automated Counter Offer (ACO) program. Id. at 9. However, even if we assume a buyer would naturally consider a basis of costs plus margin in their “limit price,” this has nothing to do with the calculation of the offer to sell price calculated in the LAP. Instead, the “limit price” in the ACO program is an offer to buy price. In addition, there is no disclosure in Lindsey that the ACO program calculates the limit price based on an updated commodity exchange price. Requester then points to the Acreage Crop Contracting (ACC) feature of TELCOT, in which the PCCA 2 buys cotton from producers in an “acreage contract,” in which producers “offer their cotton on a forward basis, contracting for the future delivery of cotton at a specific price.” Resp. Br. Req. 13; Lindsey, col. 19:63-68. A feature of this program is that the PCCA “usually re-offers these contracts to other buyers or textile mills,” “to offset its risk.” Lindsey, col. 20:11-12. Notably, however, Lindsey does not specify how the calculation of the offer to buy is made. Requester speculates that this is “easily calculated” by the exchange price (Resp. Br. Req. 9), but Lindsey does not disclose as much and the Examiner‟s rejection is not based on the ACC feature nor does the Examiner contemplate whether it would have been obvious to a person of ordinary skill in the art to calculate the offer to purchase price based on the particular factors claimed. 2 Plans Cotton Cooperative Association, creator and manager of the TELCOT system. Lindsey, col. 15:16-33. Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 10 Lastly, Requester states that the government offering price in the LAP is an exchange price but offers no claim construction analysis to support such an interpretation, nor is the Examiner‟s rejection articulated in a way that we understand the claimed “exchange price” to be read on the government offering price. Conclusion Regarding Lindsey In view of the above, we do not sustain the Examiner‟s rejections including Lindsey. Analysis of the Examiner’s Findings Regarding Kastens The Examiner made a similar error in rejection II, which relies on Kastens instead of Lindsey. The Examiner finds that Kastens describes a model that “takes into account the current market price, less storage an[d] interest costs.” RAN 83. On this basis, the Examiner finds that Kastens discloses a “flat price based on the buyer specific basis.” Id. Patent Owner apprises us of error in this finding. See App. Br. PO 22- 24. Specifically, Patent Owner points out that Kastens does not disclose the buyer-specific basis as claimed (costs plus margin) such that Kastens does not disclose a step of calculating a buyer-specific flat price as claimed. Id. The relevant passage in Kastens presents a grain storage rule, in which a grain producer looks at market prices and storage costs to determine whether to store or sell grain. Kastens 485. The calculation in Kastens is not a calculation of price but rather an expected return, determined on the basis of expected sales price and storage costs. Id. Accordingly, Kastens Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 11 does not describe a buyer-specific basis, which requires the buyer‟s costs as well as a margin. Because Kastens does not describe a buyer-specific basis in the manner required by claim 1, Kastens does not describe a calculation using that figure. Analysis of Requester’s Response Regarding Kastens Requester‟s response conflates various disclosures of Kastens that contain the word “basis.” First, Requester points to a passage in Kastens similar to that relied on by the Examiner, in which a grain storage rule for a producer is offered. Resp. Br. Req. 10 (citing Kastens 483). Requester then points to a passage in Kastens discussing that “[a]dding historical basis to deferred futures prices provides a simple and reasonably accurate procedure for using futures prices to formulate cash price expectations.” Resp. Br. Req. 10 (citing Kastens 483-4). This passage describes a calculation involving futures prices and historical basis to calculate an offer to sell price, however, not exchange price and buyer-specific basis to calculate an offer to buy price. Respondent does not present a claim construction analysis, let alone one that would persuade us that one of ordinary skill in the art would read the “calculating” claim limitation in this manner (nor has the Examiner made a rejection on this basis). As such, Requester‟s response is not persuasive. Conclusion Regarding Kastens In view of the above, we do not sustain the Examiner‟s rejection including Kastens. Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 12 Requester‟s Cross-Appeal Requester appeals the Examiner‟s decision not to adopt five rejections listed above as rejections VII-XI. We address each rejection in turn below. We sustain the Examiner‟s decision not to adopt these rejections. Rejection VII: LA Times, Herald Tribune, CTM Requester first points out that the LA Times article describes a computer making calculations that include consideration of “commissions, interest and other costs.” App. Br. Req. 10-11 (citing LA Times). Requester also points out that the computer in the LA Times article is determining whether stock price and futures price diverge enough to make a profit. App. Br. Req. 11. The combination of these, Requester, argues, equates to a “buyer-specific basis” as claimed. Turning to the LA Times article, we find a description of an automated trading program that effects an arbitrage trading scheme. LA Times, p. 2. The program operates on the principle that, for brief moments of time, the price of a stock in New York may differ from the equivalent price of a maturing future of that stock in Chicago. Id. 3 If the divergence is wide enough to make a profit (considering commissions, interests, and other costs), the computer quickly buys in one market and sells in the other. 3 A stock future is a contract between two parties to exchange stock of a particular company at a future date (the maturity date). The price of a mature stock future should then be the same as the price of the actual stock when the future matures. An arbitrage opportunity arises when this does not occur. Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 13 The Examiner found that this scheme does not describe a calculation of a price. RAN 6. We agree. The computer described in LA Times looks up two prices and calculates a delta, and then checks to see if this delta is sufficient from which to profit. Looking up a value is different from calculating a value. Requester next argues that CTM discusses hedging strategies and alleges that, in order to have such strategies, “one needs to take into account the price of the futures contract and the buyer-specific basis.” App. Br. Req. 11. Like LA Times, however, CTM does not describe the calculation of a price as claimed. Merely stating that “one needs to take into account” certain things is not the same as calculating a price. As such, the Examiner‟s finding that CTM does not teach the claimed feature (RAN 7) was correct. In view of the above, we agree with the Examiner‟s decision not to adopt this proposed rejection. Rejection VIII: LA Times, CTM, ETAP This proposed rejection includes the shortcoming discussed above with respect to LA Times and CTM. The Examiner did not adopt this rejection because the Examiner likewise did not find a calculation of a price as claimed. RAN 25. Accordingly, we agree with the decision not to adopt this proposed rejection. Rejection IX: LA Times, CTM, Marynowski This proposed rejection was not adopted by the Examiner because the Examiner found that none of the references taught the claimed calculation. Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 14 RAN 35. Requester first argues that LA Times and CTM describe the calculating step. App. Br. Req. 21. We do not agree, for the reasons set forth above with respect to rejection VII. Requester next argues that Marynowski describes this step, and reads the claimed “buyer-specific flat prices” on Marynowski‟s “theoretical buy price.” Id. at 21. The Examiner did not adopt this proposed rejection because “[n]o price calculations are discussed in [Marynowski].” RAN 33. Instead, the Examiner found Marynowski to describe “comparing prices once the prices are already established.” Id. Turning to Marynowski, we find a high-speed trading system that trades by comparing the market price of an option, for example, to a theoretical price at which the system determines it would buy the option, based on underlying market data and mathematical models using that data. See Marynowski, paras. [0058]-[0059], fig. 3. Marynowski eschews calculations and instead relies on lookup tables to decide whether to buy an option, because lookup tables are computationally much faster than calculations and even short delays “may freeze a trader out of an otherwise lucrative transaction.” Id., paras. [0040]-[0041]. Requester does not cogently explain, nor do we see, how the theoretical value of Marynowski is the “buyer-specific flat price” of claim 1. Claim 1 explicitly requires the buyer-specific flat price to be calculated from an updated commodity exchange price and a buyer-specific basis. The theoretical price in Marynowski may be based on a commodity exchange price, but not an updated one, as evidenced by the fact that Marynowski explicitly does not calculate a price at which to buy or sell based on the Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 15 current market price but rather uses the theoretical price, which in turn uses a lookup table. Notwithstanding this, the theoretical price also does not account for the claimed buyer-specific basis. Instead, the theoretical price is based on the various factors listed in paragraph [0059]. 4 The theoretical sell or buy prices, in turn, are established based upon the theoretical price and a selected “spread,” but Marynowski does not describe this spread as being a buyer-specific basis. In view of the above, we are not apprised of error in the Examiner‟s decision not to adopt this proposed rejection. Rejection X: Herald Tribune, CTM, Marynowski The difference between this rejection and rejection IX is that the primary reference is Herald Tribune instead of LA Times. Requester alleges the same or similar errors as those discussed above. See App. Br. Req. 24- 25. We are not apprised of error in the Examiner‟s decision not to adopt this proposed rejection for the reasons set forth above. Rejection XI: LA Times, Herald Tribune, Adam The issue in this rejection revolves around whether Adam describes the claimed step of “calculat[ing] . . . a buyer-specific flat price.” Requester argues that Adam describes an equation that “could be used to calculate a flat price” and that the carrying cost factor (in a different calculation) is a buyer-specific basis. App. Br. Req. 26-27 (citing Adam 88). The Examiner 4 Requester alleges that a buyer-specific basis “could” be included in these factors, but provides no evidence to support such speculation or proposed modification to Marynowski‟s teachings. App. Br. Req. 22. Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 16 found this position lacking, stating “[Adam] is addressed to calculating net return on storage hedging where the sales price is a known input, not the calculated result.” RAN 20. Turning to Adam, we find an article describing various considerations for elevator operators with respect to storage of grain and hedging. Adam 87. Particularly, Adam discloses an equation that calculates an elevator‟s net return to storage hedging. Adam 88. In addition, Adam describes how many operators make hedging decisions based on a rule of thumb, such as “[h]edge if market is offering x% of carry.” Id. In other words, the operator compares the spread between the current offer price and a future price with his or her cost to store the grain over that period of time. If the spread will cover, for example, over 70% of the carrying costs, then the operator may choose to hedge. Id. Requester‟s position that the equation in Adam “could be used to calculate a flat price” is not cogently explained. On its face, the equation calculates a net return. Thus, Requester does not persuade us of error in the Examiner‟s finding that Adam calculates a net return instead of a buyer- specific flat price. Requester‟s next position, that the carrying cost factor is a buyer- specific basis, is likewise not cogently explained. As we discussed above, a buyer-specific basis includes costs plus margin. It is not clear to us how the carrying costs are anything other than one cost considered in the buyer- specific basis. Further, even if it were a basis, the claim requires a calculation using the basis and an updated exchange price. Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 17 In view of the above, we are not apprised of error in the Examiner‟s decision not to adopt this rejection. New Ground of Rejection Lindsey in view of Admitted Prior Art Requester points out that the ‟423 patent acknowledges that it was known in the art to calculate for each buyer a buyer-specific flat price based on the buyer-specific basis and an updated commodity exchange price. App. Br. Req. 10; Reb. Br. Req. 1. Reviewing the ‟423 patent, we find admitted prior art in the section called “General Background and State of the Art.” See col. 1:28 to col. 3:45. Admitted prior art in the background of the Specification is available for rejections in an inter partes reexamination proceeding. Ex parte McGaughey, 6 USPQ2d 1334, 1337-38 (BPAI 1988) (a rejection may make use of information already established in the record); 37 C.F.R. § 1.104(c)(3); see also MPEP §§ 2617(III), 2258(I)(F). The following findings are supported by a preponderance of the evidence: 1. Lindsey describes a system and method for executing commodities transactions on a net market system called TELCOT. Lindsey, col. 17:59 to 18:13; see also id., passim. 2. TELCOT receives bids from a plurality of buyers. Id., col. 18:48- 51, 20:13-34. Because TELCOT is a computer system, in order to act on the bids, the bids must be stored in memory within the system. Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 18 3. Although TELCOT receives bids from buyers, Lindsey does not explicitly discuss the method by which buyers arrive at their bids. 4. Notwithstanding fact 3, Lindsey does state that buyers can automatically offer to purchase a commodity at a flat price (i.e., a set price available to anyone having the goods they offer to buy) based on a pre-set “limit price.” Id., col. 20:26-28. This offer to purchase is displayed to producers, who may accept the offer. Id., col. 20:16-19. 5. Also notwithstanding fact 3, Lindsey discloses that it was known in the art to have updated commodities prices available to buyers. Id., col. 20:35-40. 6. Patent Owner admitted in the “GENERAL BACKGROUND AND STATE OF THE ART” section of the ‟423 patent that it was known in the art for a commodity purchaser to offer to purchase a commodity at a price equal to the updated commodity exchange price minus the purchaser‟s basis (costs plus margin). ‟423 patent, col. 2:10-20. 7. TELCOT, being a system for executing commodities transactions, receives offers to sell specified quantities of a commodity as well as offers to buy those quantities of the commodity. See, e.g., Lindsey, col. 20:16-24 (discussing that transactions are made between buyers and sellers of particular lots of a commodity). 8. While Lindsey acknowledges that hedges involving the contracted future sale of a commodity are known in the art to be used to offset a purchaser‟s risk (id., col. 19:67 to 20:12), TELCOT does not Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 19 explicitly automatically attempt to secure a futures contract for a purchaser before executing a transaction. 9. Patent Owner admitted in the “GENERAL BACKGROUND AND STATE OF THE ART” section of the ‟423 patent that it was known in the art for a commodities purchaser to attempt to secure a futures contract to hedge risk before purchasing a commodity. ‟423 patent, col. 2:32-65 (describing how a futures contract serves to hedge risk and how to determine which contract to purchase), col. 3:1-5 (describing that the futures contract is purchased before the commodities purchase and that the sale is contingent on first acquiring the futures contract). 10. Sales in the TELCOT system result in a contract between the buyer and seller. Lindsey, col. 18:28-41. In view of the above facts, the subject matter of independent claims 1 and 16 would have been obvious to a person of ordinary skill in the art at the time of invention. While Lindsey does not describe how the Automated Counter Offer price is determined, it would have been obvious to a person of ordinary skill in the art to determine the price based on the way prices were usually determined by commodities purchasers—current exchange price minus basis. The admitted prior art makes clear that it was known to add in a margin in the basis calculation. Given that TELCOT already has the capability to determine a current, updated exchange price, it would have required nothing more than ordinary skill to further automate the ACO feature of TELCOT to allow buyers to set their “limit price” using this conventional method based on the available exchange price information. In Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 20 addition, given that it was known for purchasers to secure a futures contract before engaging in a commodities transaction, it would have been obvious to add this known feature to the ACO program, to make it further “automated” and to computerize those activities already carried out by the purchaser. These additions do nothing more than add complementary and known features for commodities purchasers. We find no evidence that such additions are outside the level of ordinary skill in the art, given the sophistication of automatic trading programs such as those described in LA Times, Herald Tribune, and Marynowski. 5 Thus, in view of the above, the subject matter of claims 1 and 16 is obvious. The subject matter of the dependent claims is likewise obvious. Not purchasing the commodity if the risk-minimizing hedge is not available (claims 2, 17) is implicit in the knowledge that one minimizes risk by getting the hedge and is explicit in the Admitted Prior Art (‟423 patent, col. 3, ll. 3-5 (“If an acceptable futures contract is obtained [then the contract moves forward]”) (emphasis added). Trying again (claims 3, 19) when something fails was a well-known technique for achieving a result. Notifying parties that a transaction occurred (claims 4, 18) is implicit in the trading process. If an offer was not accepted, it was known to try a different offer (claims 5, 20). Storing, displaying, and transmitting information used by a system, on a terminal or PC, through a network such as the Internet, and using Web pages or Web sites, were known (claims 6-8, 21, 22). Implicit in securing a futures contract are the steps of contacting a party allowed to sell such 5 These references are evidence in the record that show the level of ordinary skill in the art. Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 21 instruments, determining if such a futures contract is available, and purchasing said contract (claims 9, 23). Regarding claims 10-14 and 24-28, implicit in offering and selling lots of goods is the fact that, at times, the quantities available and/or desired will not match, but that it is beneficial to enact the transaction to the extent possible. Likewise, the lot size for the futures contracts known to be purchased along with the commodity itself may not match the actual purchased commodity amount. In order to facilitate the transaction it may be necessary that the futures contract quantity and commodities quantity will not match and one can deal with this inevitability by accepting one to be lower than the other or by purchasing more or less of one or the other to the extent possible. Regarding claims 15 and 29, because steps (e) and (f) of the base claims do not require seller action and, as we established above, it was obvious to automatically carry out these transactions, there is no reason not to have steps (e) and (f) carried out automatically without intervention of the seller. The above explanation for why the dependent claims are obvious is based on a logical extension of the knowledge one of ordinary skill in the art would have in view of Lindsey and the Admitted Prior Art. To supplement our reasons, we incorporate by reference the logic and evidence used by the Examiner in the appealed rejections. While we did not sustain the Examiner‟s rejections, this was due to a factual deficiency that was, ultimately, satisfied by Admitted Prior Art, not due to a factual deficiency Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 22 regarding the limitations of the dependent claims of which we were apprised. We enter a new ground of rejection for claims 1-29 as obvious in view of Lindsey and Admitted Prior Art consistent with the above. DECISION We REVERSE the Examiner‟s decision to reject claims 1-29 in rejections I-VI. We AFFIRM the Examiner‟s decision not to adopt rejections VII-XI. We enter a NEW GROUND of rejection for claims 1-29 as unpatentable in view of Lindsey and Admitted Prior Art. The decision contains a new ground of rejection pursuant to 37 C.F.R. § 41.77(b). Section 41.77(b) provides that “[a] new ground of rejection . . . shall not be considered final for judicial review.” That section also provides that Patent Owner, WITHIN ONE MONTH FROM THE DATE OF THE DECISION, must exercise one of the following two options with respect to the new grounds of rejection to avoid termination of the appeal proceeding as to the rejected claims: (1) Reopen prosecution. The owner may file a response requesting reopening of prosecution before the examiner. Such a response must be either an amendment of the claims so rejected or new evidence relating to the claims so rejected, or both. Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 23 (2) Request rehearing. The owner may request that the proceeding be reheard under § 41.79 by the Board upon the same record. The request for rehearing must address any new ground of rejection and state with particularity the points believed to have been misapprehended or overlooked in entering the new ground of rejection and also state all other grounds upon which rehearing is sought. In accordance with 37 C.F.R. § 41.79(a)(1), the “[p]arties to the appeal may file a request for rehearing of the decision within one month of the date of: . . . [t]he original decision of the Board under § 41.77(a).” A request for rehearing must be in compliance with 37 C.F.R. § 41.79(b). Comments in opposition to the request and additional requests for rehearing must be in accordance with 37 C.F.R. § 41.79(c), respectively. Under 37 C.F.R. § 41.79(e), the times for requesting rehearing under paragraph (a) of this section, for requesting further rehearing under paragraph (c) of this section, and for submitting comments under paragraph (b) of this section may not be extended. An appeal to the United States Court of Appeals for the Federal Circuit under 35 U.S.C. §§ 141-144 and 315 and 37 C.F.R. § 1.983 for an inter partes reexamination proceeding “commenced” on or after November 2, 2002 may not be taken “until all parties‟ rights to request rehearing have been exhausted, at which time the decision of the Board is final and appealable by any party to the appeal to the Board.” 37 C.F.R. § 41.81. See also MPEP § 2682 (8th ed., Rev. 7, July 2008). No time period for taking any subsequent action in connection with this appeal may be extended under 37 C.F.R. § 1.136(a). Requests for Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 24 extensions of time in this inter partes reexamination proceeding are governed by 37 C.F.R. § 1.956. See 37 C.F.R. § 41.79. REVERSED; 37 C.F.R. § 41.77(b) alw Appeal 2013-007499 Reexamination 95/000,432 US 7,418,423 B2 25 Patent Owner: Law Offices of Grady L. White, LLC 10605 Concord Street Suite 207 Kensington, MD 20895 Third Party Requester: Thomas J. Nikolai Nikolai & Mersereau, P.A. 900 Second Avenue South Suite 820 Minneapolis, MN 55042 Copy with citationCopy as parenthetical citation