From Casetext: Smarter Legal Research

Verition Partners Master Fund Ltd. v. Aruba Networks, Inc.

COURT OF CHANCERY OF THE STATE OF DELAWARE
Feb 15, 2018
C.A. No. 11448-VCL (Del. Ch. Feb. 15, 2018)

Opinion

C.A. No. 11448-VCL

02-15-2018

VERITION PARTNERS MASTER FUND LTD. and VERITION MULTI-STRATEGY MASTER FUND LTD., Petitioners, v. ARUBA NETWORKS, INC., Respondent.

Stuart M. Grant, Michael J. Barry, Christine M. Mackintosh, Michael T. Manuel, Rebecca A. Musarra, GRANT & EISENHOFFER P.A., Wilmington, Delaware; Attorneys for Petitioners. Michael P. Kelly, Steven P. Wood, McCARTER & ENGLISH, LLP, Wilmington, Delaware; Marc J. Sonnenfeld, Karen Pieslak Pohlmann, Laura Hughes McNally, MORGAN, LEWIS & BOCKIUS LLP, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania; Attorneys for Respondent.


MEMORANDUM OPINION

Stuart M. Grant, Michael J. Barry, Christine M. Mackintosh, Michael T. Manuel, Rebecca A. Musarra, GRANT & EISENHOFFER P.A., Wilmington, Delaware; Attorneys for Petitioners. Michael P. Kelly, Steven P. Wood, McCARTER & ENGLISH, LLP, Wilmington, Delaware; Marc J. Sonnenfeld, Karen Pieslak Pohlmann, Laura Hughes McNally, MORGAN, LEWIS & BOCKIUS LLP, Philadelphia, Pennsylvania; Attorneys for Respondent. LASTER, V.C.

In May 2015, Hewlett-Packard Company ("HP") acquired Aruba Networks, Inc. ("Aruba" or the "Company"). The transaction was governed by an Agreement and Plan of Merger by and among Aruba, HP, and Aspen Acquisition Sub., Inc., a wholly owned subsidiary of HP. Under the merger agreement, each share of Aruba common stock was converted into the right to receive consideration of $24.67 per share, subject to the holder's statutory right to eschew the merger consideration and seek appraisal. The petitioners perfected their appraisal rights and litigated this statutory appraisal proceeding. This is the court's post-trial decision on the issue of fair value.

The Delaware Supreme Court's decisions in Dell and DFC endorse using the market price of a widely traded firm as evidence of fair value. As in Dell and DFC, the market for Aruba's shares exhibited attributes associated with the premises underlying the efficient capital markets hypothesis. Under Dell and DFC, these attributes provide sufficient evidence of market efficiency to make Aruba's stock price "a possible proxy for fair value." Aruba's thirty-day average unaffected market price was $17.13 per share.

Dell, Inc. v. Magnetar Glob. Event Driven Master Fund Ltd, - A.3d -, 2017 WL 6375829 (Del. Dec. 14, 2017).

DFC Glob. Corp. v. Muirfield Value P'rs, L.P., 172 A.3d 346 (Del. 2017).

See Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *16; DFC, 172 A.3d at 369-70, 373.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *1; see also id. at *17 ("[T]he price produced by an efficient market is generally a more reliable assessment of fair value than the view of a single analyst, especially an expert witness who caters her valuation to the litigation imperatives of a well-heeled client."); DFC, 172 A.3d at 369-70 ("Market prices are typically viewed superior to other valuation techniques because, unlike, e.g., a single person's discounted cash flow model, the market price should distill the collective judgment of the many based on all the publicly available information about a given company and the value of its shares.")

The Delaware Supreme Court's decisions in Dell and DFC endorse using the deal price in a third-party, arm's-length transaction as evidence of fair value. When evaluating the reliability of the deal price, a trial judge must remember that

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *22; DFC, 172 A.3d at 367.

the purpose of an appraisal is not to make sure that the petitioners get the highest conceivable value that might have been procured had every domino fallen out of the company's way; rather, it is to make sure that they receive fair compensation for their shares in the sense that it reflects what they deserve to receive based on what would fairly be given to them in an arm's-length transaction.
Put differently, "[t]he issue in an appraisal is not whether a negotiator has extracted the highest possible bid. Rather, the key inquiry is whether the dissenters got fair value and were not exploited."

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *24.

In this case, the merger was an arm's-length transaction that provided stockholders with consideration of $24.67 per share. By definition, it provided stockholders with "fair compensation" in the sense of "what would fairly be given to them in an arm's-length transaction." The petitioners proved that the Company's negotiators might have done better, but there is no reason to believe that they left any of Aruba's fundamental value on the bargaining table. When the merger consideration of $24.67 per share is compared to the unaffected market price of $17.13 per share, it is not possible to say that Aruba's stockholders were exploited. The deal price therefore provides reliable evidence of fair value.

The Dell and DFC decisions recognize that a deal price may include synergies, and they endorse deriving an indication of fair value by deducting synergies from the deal price. The respondent's expert cited a study that provides data on the base rates at which targets successfully extract a share of anticipated synergies from acquirers. Using that data, this decision arrives at a midpoint valuation indication for Aruba of $18.20 per share. I personally believe that Aruba's negotiators did not extract as great a share of the synergies as they might have, which suggests that deal-price-less-synergies figure is slightly higher.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *13; DFC, 172 A.3d at 371.

The Dell and DFC decisions caution against relying on discounted cash flow analyses prepared by adversarial experts when reliable market indicators are available. The decisions teach that discounted cash flow models should be "used in appraisal proceedings when the respondent company was not public or was not sold in an open market check." When market evidence is available, "the Court of Chancery should be chary about imposing the hazards that always come when a law-trained judge is forced to make a point estimate of fair value based on widely divergent partisan expert testimony." In this case, the discounted cash flow analysis prepared by the petitioners' expert generated a value of $32.57, which was inconsistent with the market evidence. The discounted cash flow analysis prepared by the respondent's expert generated a value of $19.75, nestled nicely between the unaffected market price and the deal price. Its methodological underpinnings, however, provided cause for concern, as did the meandering route by which the expert arrived at his final figure. I do not rely on the discounted cash flow valuations.

See Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *26 (describing the management buy-out in that proceeding and stating that "this appraisal case does not present the classic scenario in which there is reason to suspect that market forces cannot be relied upon to ensure fair treatment of the minority"); DFC, 172 A.3d at 369 n.118 (explaining that discounted cash flow models are "often used in appraisal proceedings when the respondent company was not public or was not sold in an open market check").

DFC, 172 A.3d at 369 n.118.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *26.

The two most probative indications of fair value are Aruba's unaffected market price of $17.13 per share and my deal-price-less-synergies figure of approximately $18.20 per share. In the context of this case, the unaffected market price provides the most persuasive evidence of fair value. My deal-price-less-synergies figure suffers from two major shortcomings.

First, my deal-price-less-synergies figure is likely tainted by human error. Estimating synergies requires exercises of human judgment analogous to those involved in crafting a discounted cash flow valuation. The Delaware Supreme Court's preference for market indications over discounted cash flow valuations counsels in favor of preferring market indications over the similarly judgment-laden exercise of backing out synergies.

To cite just a few possibilities, my specific allocation of synergies to the sell-side in this case, while well intentioned, could be erroneous. The size of the original synergy estimates, while the best available under the circumstances, represented predictions about complex matters and could be wrong. More broadly, the baseline data about the manner in which buyers and sellers allocate synergies could reflect sampling or measurement errors.

See Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *26; DFC, 172 A.3d at 388; see also Applebaum v. Avaya, Inc., 812 A.2d 880, 890 (Del. 2002) ("[A] well-informed, liquid trading market will provide a measure of fair value superior to any estimate the court could impose.").

Second, my deal-price-less-synergies figure continues to incorporate an element of value derived from the merger itself: the value that the acquirer creates by reducing agency costs. A buyer's willingness to pay a premium over the market price of a widely held firm reflects not only the value of anticipated synergies but also the value created by reducing agency costs. The petitioners are not entitled to share in either element of value, because both "aris[e] from the accomplishment or expectation of the merger." The synergy deduction compensates for the one element of value arising from the merger, but a further downward adjustment would be necessary to address the other.

See William J. Carney & Mark Heimendinger, Appraising the Nonexistent: The Delaware Court's Struggle with Control Premiums, 152 U. Pa. L. Rev. 845, 847-48, 857-58, 861-66 (2003) [hereinafter Control Premiums]; Lawrence A. Hamermesh & Michael L. Wachter, Rationalizing Appraisal Standards in Compulsory Buyouts, 50 B.C. L. Rev. 1021, 1023-24, 1034-35, 1044, 1046-54, 1067 (2009) [hereinafter Rationalizing Appraisal]; Lawrence A. Hamermesh & Michael L. Wachter, The Short and Puzzling Life of the "Implicit Minority Discount" in Delaware Appraisal Law, 156 U. Penn. L. Rev. 1, 30-36, 49, 52, 60 (2007) [hereinafter Implicit Minority Discount]; Lawrence A. Hamermesh & Michael L. Wachter, The Fair Value of Cornfields in Delaware Appraisal Law, 31 J. Corp. L. 119, 128, 132-33, 139-42 (2005) [hereinafter Fair Value of Cornfields].

See Rationalizing Appraisal, supra, at 1023-24, 1038, 1046-54, 1067; Implicit Minority Discount, supra, at 30-36, 52; Fair Value of Cornfields, supra, at 139-41. The concept of reduced agency costs is the flipside of the benefits of control, which includes the ability to make changes in corporate management, strategy, and policy. See DFC, 172 A.3d at 369 n.117 (citing ability to change dividend policy). The key point is that control creates value distinct from synergy value. See Fair Value of Cornfields, supra, at 148 ("[E]xcluded gains [for purposes of appraisal] include, for example, those resulting from economies of scale or increased market share, or those that derive from the acquirer's plans to operate the post-merger enterprise more efficiently."); id. at 151 (same); accord Implicit Minority Discount, supra, at 4 (explaining that stockholders in an appraisal proceeding "do not receive value that includes synergies or benefits of control").

8 Del. C. § 262(h); see Rationalizing Appraisal, supra, at 1038 ("[T]hird-party sale value is an inappropriate standard for determining the fair value of dissenting shares because it incorporates elements of value—associated with acquisitions of control by third parties—that do not belong to the acquired enterprise or to shares of stock in that enterprise."); Implicit Minority Discount, supra, at 30 ("The value of the firm is not its third-party sale value (V3PS). In an arm's-length transaction, an acquirer will pay a premium to VE in purchasing the firm. The premium largely reflects synergies arising from the merger, but it can also reflect benefits of control."); Fair Value of Cornfields, supra, at 148 ("[E]xcluded gains [for purposes of appraisal] include, for example, those resulting from economies of scale or increased market share, or those that result from the acquirer's plans to operate the post-merger enterprise more efficiently."); id. at 151 (concluding that Section 262(h) excludes value arising from both "synergies dependent on the consummation of an arm's-length acquisition" and "operating efficiencies that arise from the acquirer's new business plans").

See Rationalizing Appraisal, supra, at 1055 (discussing an acquisition of a widely held firm and explaining that "the firm's going concern value can be estimated in this case as the actual purchase price minus synergies minus control value").

Fortunately for a trial judge, once Delaware law has embraced a traditional formulation of the efficient capital markets hypothesis, the unaffected market price provides a direct route to the same endpoint, at least for a company that is widely traded and lacks a controlling stockholder. Adjusting down from the deal price reaches, indirectly, the result that the market price already provides. Aruba's unaffected market price provides the most persuasive evidence of fair value.

See Control Premiums, supra, at 858 ("The basic conclusion of the Efficient Capital Markets Hypothesis (ECMH) is that market values of companies' shares traded in competitive and open markets are unbiased estimates of the value of the equity of such firms."); Implicit Minority Discount, supra, at 52 ("Take the case of a publicly traded company that has no controller. Efficient market theory states that the shares of this company trade at the pro rata value of the corporation as a going concern."); id. at 60 ("As a matter of generally accepted financial theory . . . , share prices in liquid and informed markets do generally represent th[e] going concern value . . . ."). Professors Hamermesh and Wachter make the same point indirectly in Rationalizing Appraisal, where they explain that market prices should not be used to determine fair value where there is either no public market price at all, where the shares are illiquid or thinly traded, or where there is a controlling stockholder. See Rationalizing Appraisal, supra, at 1033-34. Outside of these scenarios, they appear to agree that "because financial markets are efficient, one can simply use the market price," and they note that courts already rely on market price data when using the capital asset pricing model to select a discount rate or when adding a small stock premium. See id.

By awarding fair value based on the unaffected market price, this decision is not interpreting Dell and DFC to hold that market price is now the standard for fair value. Rather, Aruba's unaffected market price provides the best evidence of its going concern value. The fair value of Aruba is $17.13 per share.

See Control Premiums, supra, at 879 (noting that the appraisal statute requires consideration of all relevant factors and stating that "in an efficient market, absent information about some market failure, market price is the only relevant factor"); id. at 849 ("[W]e urge courts to presume that market value is the best measure of fair value.").

I. FACTUAL BACKGROUND

The parties reached agreement on 180 stipulations of fact in the Pre-Trial Order. Trial took place over three days. The parties submitted 996 exhibits, including eleven deposition transcripts. Three fact witnesses and three experts testified live. The parties proved the following facts by a preponderance of the evidence.

A. Aruba

Aruba was a Delaware corporation headquartered in Sunnyvale, California. Aruba went public in 2007. Until its acquisition by HP, Aruba's common stock traded on the NASDAQ under the symbol "ARUN."

Pre-Trial Order ¶¶ 27, 28. This decision cites the Pre-Trial Order as "PTO."

Aruba principally sold components for enterprise wireless local area networks ("WLANs"). From 2008 until 2014, its market share increased from 8.6% to 12.8%. Shortly before the merger, Aruba's market share peaked at 14%. Although Aruba was a significant player in the industry, Cisco Systems, Inc. dominated it. For those same years, Cisco's market share hovered around 50%.

Id. ¶¶ 63-64.

Id. ¶ 79.

See, e.g., Warmenhoven Tr. 126 (referring to Cisco as "the 800-pound gorilla"); Orr Tr. 472 (suggesting Cisco was "[p]robably more than 800 pounds").

PTO ¶ 80.

During the years leading up to the merger, Dominic Orr served as Aruba's CEO. Before joining Aruba, Orr already had enjoyed a successful career in the technology and telecommunications sectors. In 2002, in his early fifties, Orr retired to pursue a range of personal interests.

Id. ¶ 151.

See id. 56.

Orr Tr. 371-73 (describing activities during retirement, including spending time with his children, learning to cook, traveling to Japan and taking Japanese classes, working with The Philanthropy Workshop, and pursing other philanthropic endeavors including founding a non-profit business that provides low-power, solar-panel-driven phones).

In 2006, the Aruba board of directors (the "Board") lured Orr out of retirement. Orr anticipated serving for three years. But when his first term ended in 2009, the Board had not identified a successor. Orr agreed to stay on for a second three-year term, but when that term ended, the Board still had not identified a successor. At that point, Orr agreed to stay on "year by year," on the condition that Aruba seriously engage in succession planning. The Board agreed but did not move rapidly. The Board did not engage an executive search firm until 2014. Even then, the Board limited the engagement to developing a position specification for a "CEO succession review." Active recruitment would require a separate engagement. There remained "[n]o firm date" for Orr's retirement.

Orr Tr. 377. See generally id. at 368-79.

JX 248 at 1 (search firm engagement letter); see also JX 1529 (completed position specification).

JX 248 at 2.

Warmenhoven Tr. 278; see also id. at 286 (agreeing Orr "wouldn't have retired until the successful candidate had been identified"); id. at 291 ("There's no date certain."); accord Orr Tr. 459 (testifying he would remain until suitable replacement found "[t]o a certain limit. Ultimately, you know, I'm not getting younger every year.").

By the time he led the merger negotiations with HP in late 2014 and early 2015, Orr was ready to return to an active retirement. As a responsible and conscientious individual, he was not about to leave Aruba in the lurch, and he cared deeply about the Company and its employees. But he also had other things that he wanted to do with his life. The sale of Aruba to HP gave Orr a path to an honorable personal and professional exit.

See Warmenhoven Tr. 228-31; id. at 273 (Orr's "going to be 66 in March. He's told me many times that he did not want to be in a regular employment situation when he turned 65"); id. at 289 ("[H]e was going to leave before his 65th birthday.").

See Orr Tr. 380 (citing a "moral obligation to make sure that the transaction goes through, that things are reasonably integrated"); id. at 458 (agreeing he "wouldn't suddenly resign [his] position and leave Aruba without a successful, valid succession plan in place"); Warmenhoven Dep. 154 (calling Orr "the cornerstone of the entire company" and "the face to the customers, the face to the partners, and the face to the employees").

B. Wall Street Analysts Question Aruba's Financial Performance.

One of the precipitating events for the merger talks between HP and Aruba was a negative stock market reaction to Aruba's results for the third quarter of 2014. In May 2014, Aruba announced its quarterly results. Revenue exceeded both Aruba's own guidance and the Wall Street consensus estimates. But the Company reported a gross margin of 70.5%, below the consensus estimate of 72% and Aruba's "longstanding target of 71-73%."

Aruba operated on a fiscal year that ended on July 31. For Aruba, fiscal year 2015 began on August 1, 2014. Marcus Tr. 25.

See JX 47 (Barclays report); JX 48 (Janney Capital Markets report).

JX 47 at 1.

The resulting analyst coverage was harsh. Wall Street firms headlined their reports with titles like "Weak Gross Margins Outweigh Sales Upside; Maintain Market Perform" and "FY3Q14: Disappointing Gross Margin Offsets Ongoing 802.11ac Ramp." Aruba's stock price dropped 12.11% on the news, from $20.06 to $17.63.

JX 259 at 2-3 (email collecting analyst coverage).

The parties originally provided limited data on the stock price. See JX 245. As part of the supplemental briefing process, the respondent provided more extensive data. See Dkt. 188 Ex. A (publicly available stock-price data for Aruba and S&P 500). The trading data is suitable for judicial notice. See Lee v. Pincus, 2014 WL 6066108, at *4 n.11 (Del. Ch. Nov. 14, 2014) ("I take judicial notice of these reported stock prices because they are not subject to reasonable dispute." (citing D.R.E. 201(b)(2); In re Gen. Motors (Hughes) S'holder Litig., 897 A.2d 162, 169 (Del. 2006))).

Internally, Aruba management was disappointed. They had not anticipated the furor over gross margins. Orr vented to the Board: "[W]e, as an executive team, are finally sick of wall st discrediting our tremendous come back in revenue growth because they said we are not as profitable as Ubiquiti (give me a break!)."

See JX 260 at 5-6 (email thread among management); Warmenhoven Tr. 235 ("It was very frustrating for the management team, I must say. I mean, in -- in fiscal year 2014, they had 20 percent year-over-year growth, and we were delivering everything to the street, and the stock really didn't move.").

JX 260 at 1 (email from Aruba's Vice President of Sales that he was "not sure we had any real insights [into the gross margins] until it was too late.")

JX 267; see also JX 269 at 2 (Orr email to Aruba's CFO: "Between you and me, if we do all these and our stock price stays $13-20, you and I fail miserably. I don't know why we are doing all these [sic] tough stuff. I really don't."). Ubiquiti Networks, Inc. is one of Aruba's competitors.

To improve margins, Aruba management developed a cost optimization plan called "Project Greyhound." It contemplated eliminating approximately 130 employees and relocating another eighty to "lower-cost geographies." Management undertook the project because the "Company value [was] not adequately reflected in [the] stock price."

PTO ¶ 101.

JX 280 at 10-11 (internal Aruba deck on Project Greyhound); JX 285 (email from Orr announcing Project Greyhound internally as part of an effort to "continue to evaluate all aspects of our business to ensure that we achieve our full potential and that we are able to invest in our strategic initiatives and infrastructure"); see also Warmenhoven Tr. 217-18 (discussing Project Greyhound); Orr Tr. 413-14 (same); id. at 477-78 (reaffirming statements in JX 285).

JX 273 at 2 (draft internal talking points); see also Orr Tr. 486 (suggesting Project Greyhound was motivated, in part, by management's belief that the stock price "does not reflect what we believe is our commitment to deliver to what the analysts and the investors want us to do"); Galvin Tr. 597-98 (acknowledging Aruba undertook Project Greyhound, in part, because "we did have pressure from Wall Street to improve what we were dropping to the bottom line"); id. at 600 (agreeing "Greyhound was initiated because there was a perception that the company value was not adequately reflected in the stock price").

In August 2014, Aruba announced its results for the full year of 2014, including quarterly results for the fourth quarter. Aruba achieved record revenue. Orr told investors that Aruba had achieved "significant market share gains" and had a "strong platform for future growth." Aruba simultaneously announced the implementation of Project Greyhound.

JX 828 (press release announcing results); see also JX 637 at 3 (earnings call transcript announcing "[o]ur Q4 results exceeded our guidance on all fronts," "[w]e saw bookings growth in all of our major [sic] with particular sequential strength in North America," and "[w]e delivered solid year-over-year growth in all of our core verticals plus notable strength in the enterprise markets"); Orr Tr. 477 (confirming revenue for fiscal year 2014 grew 21% from prior year); Galvin Tr. 545-46 (discussing fiscal year 2014 generally and acknowledging it "was a strong year for the company").

JX 828; JX 637 at 4 (announcing "we have identified opportunities to optimize our cost structure by eliminating certain positions").

The analysts' reactions were mixed. Some were positive. Others were more cautious. Traders bid up Aruba's stock price by 8%, from $20.24 to $22.01.

See JX 59 at 2 (JMP Securities report commenting favorably on revenue); JX 62 at 1 (BMO Capital Markets report commenting favorably on Project Greyhound); see also JX 309 at 7 (Aruba Board deck summarizing analyst reports and noting that fifteen analysts increased their target price).

See JX 61 at 1 (Wells Fargo Securities report positing that "[g]ood news mostly priced in" and advising caution "due to valuation and increased competition from Cisco"); JX 64 at 1 (Deutsche Bank report affirming "hold" recommendation in light of risks that "1) unpredictable sales cycles could adversely impact sales 2) highly competitive marketplace could pressure margins").

JX 245.

C. HP Approaches Aruba.

HP had been monitoring Aruba as an acquisition candidate. HP felt it had strong offerings in the wired networking space and wanted to combine those products with Aruba's wireless offerings. HP believed the combined product set could compete effectively with Cisco and take significant market share.

See, e.g., Johansson Dep. 59-60 ("[T]here was a strong desire from customers to have a converged network portfolio and a converged product solution, and we felt that combining the two companies we would really create a unique offering in the market, which today you can only get from Cisco."); id. at 248 (acknowledging anticipated $1.6 billion in synergies from transaction); Whitman Dep. 54 ("Hewlett-Packard would feel entitled to those synergies because probably our go-to-market, our G&A, would be enabling those synergies."); see also Orr Tr. 396 (acknowledging "[t]his is a really, really optimal situation to leverage two companies' assets" because HP had "the switching line" but "a very, very weak wireless" and "Aruba has the mobility software and the security software . . . and the wireless reputation and portfolio"); id. at 434 (confirming "that the HP-Aruba combination offered synergies to both"); JX 345 at 5 (internal HP deck touting deal as providing "complementary go to market and wireless capabilities, bolstering our Enterprise Mobility offering, and uniquely positioning HP as the market moves towards a unified wired/wireless solution").

On August 27, 2014, the day after Aruba announced its full-year earnings, HP approached Aruba about a deal. Antonio Neri, a Senior Vice President at HP, contacted Orr. Orr promptly notified Daniel Warmenhoven, Aruba's lead independent director. Warmenhoven, in turn, contacted Frank Quattrone, a senior investment banker at Qatalyst Partners LP.

PTO ¶ 151.

See Warmenhoven Tr. 236-37.

JX 291 at 5 (email from Quattrone to Orr: "I just spoke to Dan [Warmenhoven]. Can we chat early tomorrow morning, say around 7am?").

The next day, Warmenhoven notified the full Aruba Board of HP's interest. He also reported that he had contacted Quattrone and that Orr would contact Stuart Francis, an investment banker who had recently left Barclays Capital Inc. to join Evercore Group L.L.C. Warmenhoven told the other directors that HP wanted to proceed "quickly and present the proposal to the [HP] board on Sept[ember] 16."

See JX 288 (email from Warmenhoven to Aruba Board); see also JX 859 (press release announcing Francis's new position); see also Warmenhoven Tr. 240; id. at 249 (calling Francis "probably the world's best banker").

JX 288.

Qatalyst jumped at the potential engagement. Immediately after hearing from Warmenhoven, Quattrone reached out to Orr and sent him a proposed engagement letter. Two days later, George Boutros, another senior banker with Qatalyst, sent Orr a "[s]cript for [d]iscussion with H[P]." Meanwhile, Warmenhoven reconsidered reaching out to Francis. Warmhoven "had no experience with Evercore" and "didn't know the team."

JX 289 (email from Quattrone to Orr forwarding draft engagement letter); JX 291 at 4-5.

JX 291 at 3.

Warmenhoven Tr. 241.

On August 29, 2014, Neri again spoke with Orr. Neri insisted that HP was serious. Orr tried to "delicately set expectations that this is going to be a high premium deal."

JX 291 at 2.

On September 1, 2014, Neri and Orr met in person. A talking point that Boutros prepared for the meeting stressed the importance of price: "[T]here will have to be a very substantial premium to market, well in excess of the typical m&a premium, in order to fully reflect both the substantial upside potential we have as an independent company, and our strategic value to you and others."

JX 292 at 1.

On September 2, 2014, Warmenhoven spoke with HP's CEO, Meg Whitman. She confirmed HP's interest. Later that day, the Aruba Board met. Orr described the developments with HP and reported that HP had not yet proposed "any financial terms or other parameters regarding a possible strategic transaction."

JX 909 at 47. This decision cites Aruba's definitive proxy statement, introduced as JX 909, as the "Proxy."

JX 228 at 1 (minutes).

During the meeting, members of the Board expressed concern about having Qatalyst advise the Company in discussions with HP. Qatalyst had represented Autonomy Corporation PLC when HP bought it for $11 billion in 2011. The deal was widely understood to have been a "disaster" for HP that resulted in an $8.8 billion write-down and protracted litigation. HP's acquisition of Aruba would be its first significant deal since Autonomy. The directors wondered if HP would balk at working across from Qatalyst.

PTO ¶¶ 32-35.

JX 731 (Financial Times article).

PTO ¶¶ 32-34.

Warmenhoven Tr. 243 ("And the question was, does [the Autonomy transaction] leave any residual -- negative residual with Hewlett-Packard. And would it cause a problem if Qatalyst represented it in another transaction to HP."); Orr Tr. 331-32 (confirming Aruba Board "discussed the fact that Qatalyst had previously represented Autonomy in the sale to Hewlett-Packard" as well as "whether that prior history might 'put a strain on the relationship' between . . . Qatalyst and HP").

When Warmenhoven raised these concerns with Quattrone and Boutros, they reassured him that (i) Qatalyst had worked off of Autonomy's audited financials and was as much a victim as anyone else, (ii) HP understood this, (iii) the entire HP M&A team had turned over since Autonomy, and (iv) Qatalyst had a good relationship with the new team. The Aruba Board accepted these reassurances.

Warmenhoven Tr. 243-44 (testifying Qatalyst representatives were "candid and direct in their answers" and asserted that "they were representing audited financials . . . so they didn't think that HP would harbor any grudge," that "[t]here had been a complete turnover of the M&A team," and that "[w]e work well with these people"); see also Orr Tr. 332 (confirming "Qatalyst assured the board that [Autonomy] wasn't going to be a problem").

With the Autonomy concerns allayed, Qatalyst and Aruba negotiated the terms of Qatalyst's engagement letter. Qatalyst projected that a deal price "around $30" per share was "the most likely outcome" and proposed a fee equal to 1.25% of the transaction value for a deal at $30 per share or higher. Qatalyst proposed a richer fee of 1.5% for a price at $36 or higher. Qatalyst felt that a price below $30 warranted 1% of deal value.

JX 303 at 2 (internal Aruba email recounting negotiations).

Id.

Aruba's CFO, Mike Galvin, pushed back. He pointed out that "it's universally thought that [Aruba] is undervalued right now" and, therefore, a price at the higher end of the range was a strong possibility. Orr agreed with Galvin's assessment. He stressed that the "board doesn't want [a] deal below $30; I want it above $33." He further advised that he was "not comfy [with] a ramp from 30 to 33," because "[i]t would not be spicy enough" to incentivize Qatalyst "to focus on the 33-35 target range we want." After heated negotiations, the final engagement letter provided for a flat 1% fee.

Id. at 1.

Id.

Id.; see also Orr Tr. 512-14 (discussing JX 303 but stating Boutros had advised that "without . . . a truly competing situation, I think the deal's going to get done with a 2 in front of it" and that "[s]tarting with a 3 [in front] would be unrealistic")

PTO ¶ 42; JX 305 at 2-3 (signed engagement letter).

D. The Discussions With HP Move Forward.

Orr and Neri met again on September 10, 2014. Orr emphasized Aruba's strong results, its willingness to remain independent, and the synergies that a deal would produce. Internal HP analyses confirmed the potential for substantial synergies.

See JX 308 (talking points for Orr including, "we are not trying to sell the company and both the management team and the board are very bullish about our prospects as an independent company," "a combination could be very powerful," and "the price would have to be very compelling to take us off our current path which we know will result in significant shareholder value").

See JX 310 at 1-2 (internal HP email summarizing conversation between Orr and Neri, stating Aruba "would like to have a deeper conversation around how serious we are and our willingness to execute the plan/synergies," and requesting a write-up on "why [Aruba]+HP is better" and "[o]ur view of the synergies"); JX 312 at 3, 5 (resulting write-up stressing "[w]e believe that there are meaningful revenue synergies" because "[c]ombined, the companies would have a leading converged campus solution" and significant "cross-selling" opportunities).

On September 15, 2014, HP kicked off its due diligence. From that point on, management representatives at various levels met on a series of occasions. The speed and intrusiveness of HP's diligence surprised Orr. In a discussion with Neri on September 18, Orr stressed that for a transaction to occur, HP would "have to pay a very compelling price that reflects both the significant upside potential that we have ahead of us, and the strategic value of Aruba . . . . This means that this deal will not happen at a conventional M&A premium."

See JX 319 at 2-5 (emails coordinating meetings between Aruba and HP management); Proxy at 48-49.

JX 319 at 6 (Aruba talking points prepared for Orr: "I was frankly surprised by the breadth and scope of the information request, as it was not consistent with the message I thought you conveyed to me when we last spoke.").

Id.

E. No Other Strategic Buyers Show Interest.

On September 25, 2014, the Aruba Board authorized Qatalyst to contact other potential buyers to gauge their interest. Qatalyst developed a preliminary list. The Board instructed Qatalyst to focus on "a limited number of third parties with financial wherewithal and a strategic interest in mobile technology" that would enjoy "compelling synergies" so that the buyer could be "competitive with any potential proposal from [HP]." The Board instructed Qatalyst not to contact any private equity firms, believing that "given the Company's volatile revenues and unpredictable cash flows and the potential for synergies between Aruba's business with a strategic acquiror, private equity firms would not be competitive in their potential valuations."

JX 229 at 1 (minutes); accord JX 327 at 3 (Qatalyst board deck).

JX 229 at 1-2.

Id. at 2; accord Proxy at 48; Warmenhoven Tr. 259 (testifying Aruba did not contact financial bidders because "they like steady-state businesses, cash-cow businesses, and, you know, something that's just this volatile doesn't fit that profile" and because "they're what I will refer to as bottom-feeders," describing them as "generally low-ball bidders, very small premiums").

Qatalyst identified thirteen "Selected Potential Partners." Between September 29 and October 4, 2014, Qatalyst approached five of them. By October 9, each had declined. Boutros explained that "[i]t was very clear that none of them had any interest in an acquisition" and that it had "nothing to do with price." Orr concluded that "[n]ow our only (but strong) weapon is to say we go alone." Boutros was "not at all troubled by that," observing that it was "what we expected anyway."

JX 757 at 17 (draft Qatalyst board deck).

JX 760 (Qatalyst "Outreach Summary"); see Warmenhoven Tr. 256-58, 329-31 (describing outreach); Orr Tr. 440-42 (same).

JX 760 at 2 (chart showing status of each investor as "Declined to Proceed"); Proxy at 48-49.

Boutros Dep. 219; accord Warmenhoven Tr. 260 ("[I]t was definitive noninterest."); id. 329-30 (agreeing potential bidders provided "feedback" that they "had no strategic interest in acquiring Aruba" and that it "[h]ad nothing to do with the price").

JX 341 at 1.

Id.

F. The Parties' Initial Valuations

In early October 2014, Aruba provided HP with a set of internal projections based on figures from Aruba's revised three-year strategic financial plan, which Aruba had prepared in the ordinary course of business in June (the "June Plan"). In August, Galvin and his finance team had updated the June Plan to incorporate the effects of Project Greyhound and to make the plan more conservative. They had reduced the anticipated revenue growth rate for 2016 and 2017 and adopted more conservative assumptions for bookings, gross margin, and operating margin. In September, the Aruba team reviewed the numbers with Qatalyst, describing the plan as a "medium" case that was "more moderate" than the June Plan. By early October, the Aruba team and Qatalyst had created a more bullish set of projections that forecasted revenue consistent with the June Plan (the "October Projections"). Using the October Projections and a discounted cash flow methodology, Qatalyst derived a valuation range for Aruba of $23.50 to $31.08 per share.

See Warmenhoven Tr. 219-20; id. at 313-14 (confirming Galvin prepared the June Plan "in the spring of 2014, as part of the normal operations" of the Company); Galvin Tr. 553-54 (discussing development of "top-down" projections incorporating "broader strategic assumptions" discussed by the Aruba Board regularly at the "June meeting"). See generally PTO ¶¶ 110-14.

See JX 297 at 2 (email from Galvin to member of the finance team: "I think we need to make this more conservative than the 3 [year] plan."); see also Warmenhoven Tr. 314-15 (discussing Aruba's ordinary process of preparing a yearly operating plan in September); Galvin Tr. 586 (acknowledging September figures adjusted margins, reflecting "[t]he overall impacts" of Project Greyhound).

JX 315 at 1 (email from Galvin to Qatalyst banker).

Proxy at 64; see also Warmenhoven Tr. 315; Galvin Tr. 587.

JX 342 at 4 (internal Qatalyst emails attaching draft discounted cash flow model).

HP's internal deal team used the October Projections to prepare a discounted cash flow valuation of its own. HP estimated Aruba's value as a standalone company at $18.76 per share. But HP also estimated that a transaction between Aruba and HP would generate $1.4 billion in revenue synergies and another $300 million in cost synergies. With synergies, the team estimated that the pro forma value of Aruba could be as high as $32.05 per share.

JX 345 at 20.

Id. at 15-16.

Id. at 20.

G. HP Begins Recruiting Orr.

While the HP deal team was internally developing its pricing parameters, the senior members of the team continued their discussions with Orr. Neri and Orr had a "pretty open dialogue," and Orr "remain[ed] positive about [HP's] approach." Neri understood from Orr that Aruba was "not running a sales process," and Orr made no effort to "postur[e] about trying to pin [HP] against someone else."

JX 348 (email from Neri to Whitman).

Johansson Dep. 112.

In early November 2014, HP's Global Head of Corporate Development, Joakim Johansson, met with Orr. In an email to Qatalyst and other Aruba executives, Orr recounted that Johansson let him "know clearly that, post combination, they expect me to run the whole networking business." Orr said that Johansson wanted "to look me in the eye and see that I have no objection. I told him I have no objection."

JX 349 at 1.

Id.; see also Orr Tr. 462-66 (confirming solicitation and that "part of the reason they are willing to pay a premium for the Aruba price is for my leadership").

HP's solicitation of Orr violated the terms of a confidentiality agreement that HP had entered into with Aruba on October 2, 2014. That agreement contained a non-solicit provision, which stated:

HP hereby agrees that, except to the extent expressly authorized by the board of directors of the Company (or any authorized committee thereof) in advance, neither HP nor any of its Representatives acting on its behalf will directly or indirectly have any formal or informal discussions, or directly or indirectly enter into any agreement, arrangement or understanding (whether or not binding), with any director, officer or other employee of the Company relating to (i) any retention, severance or other compensation, incentives or benefits that may be or become payable to any directors, officers or employees of the Company in connection with the Transaction or following the consummation thereof, or (ii) any directorship, employment, consulting arrangement or other similar association or involvement of any directors, officers or other employees of the Company with HP or any of its businesses or operations following the consummation of a Transaction.
The Aruba Board had not authorized HP's solicitation of Orr.

JX 3 § 8.

Orr Tr. 463-64 (agreeing Aruba Board had not authorized discussion).

H. The HP Board Balks.

On November 6, 2014, the HP deal team asked Whitman to approve paying up to $3 billion for Aruba, or $26.66 per share. In its presentation to Whitman, the deal team scaled back the synergies slightly, with revenue synergies of $1.26 billion and cost synergies of $295 million. The pro forma, with-synergies discounted cash flow value of Aruba declined to $31.17 per share. Whitman backed the acquisition; the next step was to obtain authority from HP's board of directors (the "HP Board").

JX 350 at 4 (internal deck prepared for presentation to Whitman).

Id. at 14-15.

Id. at 20.

JX 356 (internal deck prepared for HP Board subcommittee). See generally Johansson Dep. 22-24 (discussing HP approval process).

On November 20, 2014, Aruba announced its earnings for the first quarter of 2015. Management described an "outstanding quarter" that included "[r]ecord revenues" that exceeded "the top end of [their] guidance range." Management also reported that Project Greyhound had improved margins, "with non-GAAP operating margin growing to 21.8%." But Aruba also announced a range of revenue guidance for the second quarter of 2015 that was 1% lower at the midpoint than the pre-announcement analyst consensus. Analysts fixated on the lowered guidance. Although Aruba management explained that they were trying to be prudent, Aruba's stock dropped by 14%, closing at $18.82.

JX 638 at 3 (transcript from Aruba earnings call).

Id. at 4.

JX 363 (internal HP email transmitting Barclays analyst report).

JX 638 at 13 (Galvin stating Aruba was "just being prudent in a mixed environment" and "[n]ot getting ahead of our skis"); see also JX 355 at 1 (email from Galvin to Aruba Board: "our guide is shaping up to be more cautious than our strong results").

JX 245.

The HP deal team saw the price drop as an opportunity to buy Aruba at a discount. Internally, HP acknowledged that Aruba's results were "better than we expected," that they validated the case that the deal team had presented to the HP Board, and that "[t]he softer guidance did not cause us to change our financial model."

See JX 357 at 1 (internal email among members of the HP deal team: "They are down 8% after hours though because of guidance below consensus for this quarter (although it looks like the range of guidance is still within expectations). Good time to pull the trigger and snap them up I would say."); Hardegree Dep. 193 (observing that the stock price drop "probably did, on balance" put HP "in a more tacti[cally] advantaged position").

JX 362 at 1.

JX 357 at 1 (Neri: "We told our story and we were on point."); see also JX 360 (email from HP Senior Vice President of Corporate Development: "I thought the results were pretty good. . . . They blew past the revenue expectations for the quarter. But they guided soft, below consensus.").

JX 780 at 2 (internal HP deck discussing November earnings announcement).

The HP Board, however, remained skittish after the Autonomy fiasco, and it was not ready to authorize a bid. Neri told Orr that the HP Board had questions about the deal and that it would take another two or three weeks to answer them.

JX 328 (email from Orr to Aruba Board reporting that "Antonio [Neri] said that [HP] needs another 2-3 weeks to address the board's questions").

Orr felt the process had dragged on long enough, and he recommended that the Aruba Board terminate discussions. With the Aruba Board's backing, management conveyed that Aruba was moving on. Aruba formally terminated discussions on November 25.

Id. ("We have been in dialogue with [HP] since August 27, and have not received a proposal in all this time. . . . We cannot continue to wait for them."); accord Proxy at 48-49

JX 372 at 1 (email from Aruba General Counsel relaying conversation with Johansson during which she explained that "[w]e feel it's time to suspend discussions" because "it has reached a point where we need to focus on running our business and not be distracted by discussions that did not seem to be progressing"); see also Orr Tr. 448-49 ("So we are basically saying, if you cannot get it done, let's cool off. And when you are ready, contact me again.").

See JX 328; JX 367 (email from Aruba to Qatalyst advising it had "decided to terminate discussions with [HP] at this time" and that it would "let [Qatalyst] know if discussions resume").

I. HP Engages Advisors And Continues Analyzing The Deal.

After Aruba terminated discussions, HP continued working on the deal. In late November 2014, HP engaged McKinsey & Company to validate its business case for the acquisition. McKinsey concluded that HP could expect market share gains and revenue and cost synergies that were in line with HP management's estimates.

JX 383 at 1, 3 (McKinsey report projecting "share gains in line with what is in the business case (2.6-3.1% share gain in wired vs. 3% in the business case and correspondingly 4.3-5.6% share gain in wireless vs. 7% in the business case)").

In December 2014, HP engaged Barclays as its financial advisor. At the time, Barclays had an existing relationship with Aruba, having worked with Aruba on a potential convertible debt financing since June 2013. The debt financing had been ready to launch in September 2014, but Aruba declined to move forward. The lead banker at Barclays inferred that Aruba was considering a major M&A transaction. Barclays spent the next three months trying to get a role representing Aruba, until they secured the engagement for HP. Barclays also was one of two banks executing Aruba's ongoing share repurchase program, which had been in place since June 2012. In February 2014, the Aruba Board had authorized management to repurchase up to $500 million of Aruba's common stock in the open market at prices up to $25 per share. When approving the repurchases, the Board made the following determination: "The recent trading price of the Company's stock on the NASDAQ Global Select Market has been depressed and the Board believes that the trading price of the Company's common stock may be undervalued . . . ." Aruba management suspended the repurchases in October 2014 because of the discussions with HP. After terminating discussions with HP in November 2014, Orr recommended resuming the repurchase program and buying shares worth up to $75 million, because "the stock is underperforming." Aruba resumed its repurchases at up to $25 per share, believing its shares to be undervalued below that figure.

See JX 387 (internal Barclays email dated December 19: "HP wants to have our views on value on Monday"); JX 389 (email from Barclays to HP on December 22 providing "the deck we plan to review on our 10am conference call").

See PTO ¶¶ 51, 54; JX 224 (Aruba Board subcommittee minutes); Galvin Tr. 601. Evercore was also advising in connection with the potential debt financing. See JX 286 (email from Francis to Orr and Galvin discussing fiscal year 2014 results ahead of "meeting on the convertible market").

JX 325 at 1 (email from Galvin relaying conversation wherein he told Barclays banker Aruba would not be executing the convertible offering and banker responded "in my business, when this happens, either an exec is leaving the company or a major M&A [transaction] is in process").

See, e.g., JX 335 at 2 (email from Barclays banker to Aruba management: "[W]e're hearing (from non-Aruba sources) that HP has reinitiated dialogue with you" and "[w]e want to be as helpful as we can."); id. at 1 (describing phone call in which Barclays banker reminded Orr that "we helped you with the Barclay IT people, we walked away from [the] Ruckus IPO when Galvin said it was competitive . . . , [and] we have done a lot [o]f work to support you in the last 8 years"); id. (banker telling Orr that Barclays "would be disappointed if the HP rumor is true and you do not work with us"); JX 384 (email between Barclays bankers: "I am trying to get back in front of the Aruba team. Seems like we have given up on the HP side.").

PTO ¶ 53; JX 227 (minutes). See generally Galvin Tr. 594-96 (discussing share repurchase program).

JX 226 at 1-2 (minutes).

PTO ¶ 133.

See id. ¶ 136.

JX 328.

See JX 373 at 1 (internal Aruba emails discussing share repurchase program); see also Orr Tr. 448 (testifying that, in breaking off discussions, he considered that "[w]e have a stock buy-back program that . . . we have to resume"); Galvin Tr. 595-96 (discussing the share repurchase and stating "[w]e had a standard set of language that, when we approached these things, that it may be depressed, it may be undervalued").

Using consensus analyst estimates for Aruba's standalone performance, Barclays provided HP with a range of discounted cash flow values for Aruba as a standalone company and compared them with pro forma values for Aruba that incorporated synergies.

JX 389 at 16-17 (Barclays deck).

Discount Rate

Perpetuity Growth Rate

2%

3%

4%

Street

Synergy

Street

Synergy

Street

Synergy

11%

$19.31

$29.49

$20.86

$32.29

$22.85

$35.89

12%

$17.61

$26.45

$18.80

$28.62

$20.30

$31.32

13%

$16.21

$23.98

$17.16

$25.69

$18.32

$27.78

Barclay's valuation work confirmed the HP deal team's internal estimates.

J. HP Approaches Aruba Again.

Meanwhile, Aruba's stock price remained stuck around $18-19 per share, and analysts continued to criticize the Company. Orr felt that the analysts had soured on Aruba and were complaining about everything. Galvin expressed frustration that analysts seemed unwilling to "acknowledge the 6 very strong [quarters] in a row we've had." One analyst suggested to Aruba management that the stock price was low enough to justify an accelerated buyback, observing that if management did not pursue that option, an activist might. A group of investors met with management and privately criticized the Company's performance.

Orr Tr. 454 (comparing analysts to "somebody [who] has decided to get out of a relationship" because "the other party can learn how to cook, clean the floor, you know, be available on the weekend, and so on. Something is always wrong."); see also JX 406 at 1 (email from Orr: "we simply cannot miss Q2 and have the stock tanked further, risking employee morale and retention getting into an unrepairable state").

JX 378 at 2 (email among Aruba executives).

JX 374 at 1 (email from Jason Adler, analyst at William Blair & Company).

See JX 377 (email from Galvin recapping meeting).

Against this backdrop, in late December 2014, Whitman and Neri invited Orr to dinner. The meeting took place on January 21, 2015. Whitman told Orr that HP still wanted to acquire Aruba. Orr responded positively and suggested that they try to sign up a deal by early March. He told Whitman that Aruba had "over 2000 customers and partners coming to Atmosphere 2015 in Vegas the week of March 1-5," and "[i]t would be silly not to announce it there." Whitman "completely agreed," observing "that, in her experience, mergers need forcing function and let this be the one."

PTO ¶ 154; JX 392 (correspondence between Orr and Neri scheduling dinner).

PTO ¶ 155.

JX 423 (email from Orr relaying conversation to Aruba management); see also Orr Tr. 524-25.

JX 423; see also Orr Tr. 527 ("We're saying that let's use this as a forcing function.").

Whitman also told Orr that HP would not work with Qatalyst under any circumstances. That same night, Orr told Warmenhoven that "Meg [Whitman] spoke with conviction and emotion over dinner that they [Qatalyst] were guilty. Qatalyst will argue the reverse, but it does not matter." Orr concluded that "if we don't insert [a] buffer person, our negotiation will suffer severely." To resolve the problem, Warmenhoven doubled back to the solution he had previously dismissed: using Francis. Warmenhoven reminded Orr that Francis "is in a new firm and not conflicted, and Meg [Whitman] knows and (I think) trusts him." He offered to call Whitman to see if involving Francis would be acceptable.

JX 412 at 1. Warmenhoven disputed at trial whether he correctly understood Orr to be saying that Whitman felt that Qatalyst, rather than Autonomy, was guilty. His deposition transcript indicates that his counsel planted this idea. See Warmenhoven Tr. 336-40; Warmenhoven Dep. 141-43 ("[Aruba counsel]: If you are going to move off of this, would you mind if I clarify one point? [Verition counsel]: Okay, that's fine. [Aruba counsel]: Mr. Warmenhoven, if you don't mind my interjecting -- The Witness: No, I know where you're going. . . . That's how I interpreted it at that time. That's not right. Meg [Whitman's] conviction was that Autonomy was guilty -- not Qatalyst -- that Autonomy was guilty of fraud."). Aruba's counsel should not have influenced the substance of Warmenhoven's testimony during his deposition. Nor should counsel have been reshaping Warmenhoven's recollection of the facts.

JX 412 at 1; see also Warmenhoven Tr. 247-49 (discussing JX 412); Orr Tr. 449-51 (same).

JX 412 at 1.

Id.; accord Warmenhoven Tr. 249-51; Orr Tr. 451 ("Obviously, the top of mind is the person that I started out with, and that has been a trusted advisor to the company and to me, and that was Stu [Francis].").

On January 23, 2015, Warmenhoven updated the Aruba Board. He reported that Aruba should receive a formal offer letter soon. He explained that "[w]e do have a bit of an issue and that is our choice of advisors. [HP] is very anti [Qatalyst]." He reminded the Board that the Company already had a signed engagement letter with Qatalyst, so Aruba would have to pay Qatalyst regardless, but he suggested hiring Francis to handle the negotiations. Warmenhoven pointed out that "Evercore is new in the tech sector, so they may be willing to do a deal at ¼% just to get a deal done that they can brag about publicly."

JX 413.

Id.; accord JX 414 (email from Orr to Warmenhoven: "I think Qatalyst will not be willing to carve out fees for Stu [Francis]."); JX 426 at 2 (internal Aruba email summarizing discussions with Francis concerning fees: "He started at Evercore 5 months ago and is their first tech sector person. They want this deal to establish a presence in tech."); see also PTO ¶ 46 ("J. Stuart Francis is a Senior Managing Director of Evercore. Mr. Francis joined Evercore in the summer of 2014.").

Warmenhoven spoke with Whitman that same day. She told him that "Qatalyst, Frank [Quattrone] & George [Boutros] are not welcome in the negotiations. The issue is bigger than Autonomy and goes back to EBay & Yahoo." Whitman described Boutros as "evil." But Whitman said that she would happily negotiate with either Francis or Warmhoven, as long as Qatalyst stayed "in the back room." She also wanted Qatalyst "squeezed a bit" on their fees.

JX 420 (email from Warmenhoven recounting discussion to Aruba Board and management).

Id.

Id.; accord Warmenhoven Tr. 252-53 (Whitman told Warmenhoven "I don't care who you get, but it can't be Qatalyst" and that "I'm not going to take into my boardroom a deal proposed by Qatalyst"); id. at 341-45; Orr Tr. 530.

JX 432 at 1 (email among Aruba management discussing negotiation of Qatalyst's fees).

Aruba retained Evercore that day. Francis reported to his partners that the "[d]eal timing is to try to sign a merger agreement and announce by mid February." His partners were thrilled. One replied: "Truly amazing! This is a franchise transaction! Well done!" Another responded: "This is franchise defining. Well done, and it shows the power of loyalty, which you have always eschewed! [sic]" A third offered: "Just remarkable, Stu[.] What a coup! Would be, as you say, a dynamic advance for Evercore in The Valley."

JX 422 at 1 (email among Evercore senior bankers).

JX 427.

Id.

JX 428; accord JX 439 (congratulatory emails from two additional senior bankers).

K. Qatalyst Tries To Repair Its Relationship With HP.

Qatalyst was as crushed by the news as Evercore was elated. When Orr told Boutros, he was "so emotional, defensive AND offensive (to Meg [Whitman]) that he hardly let me talk." Quattrone asked Warmenhoven to intervene with Whitman on his behalf, and Warmenhoven asked Whitman to meet personally with Quattrone. Quattrone then sent Whitman an email of his own:

JX 426 (email from Orr to Aruba management updating on negotiations with Qatalyst). Orr expressed his opinion that Boutros "reacted so strongly cause (1) pride of their brand (2) reaction to Stu [Francis] coming in[to] the picture [and] (3) protecting their fees." Id. He noted that "[n]one of the above related to the benefits of [A]ruba!" Id.

JX 430.

I was very surprised and disappointed to learn from Dan Warmenhoven today that you recently expressed very strong negative feelings about our firm, some of our people (including me) and our current representation of Aruba. I would greatly appreciate the opportunity to speak or meet with you at your earliest convenience to understand from you directly what your concerns are and give me the opportunity to address them. . . . [W]hile our loyalties are always to our client on any assignment, I am confident we can address your concerns, play a constructive role and engage with your team in a professional manner.
When Whitman did not respond, Warmenhoven followed up the next day, vouched for Qattrone, and expressed confidence that "if you two could 'clear the air' [then] Frank [Quattrone] and [Qatalyst] could be constructive participants in getting this deal done."

JX 434 at 1.

JX 436 at 1. See generally Warmenhoven Tr. 344-45 (recounting process of attempting to ingratiate Qatalyst with HP).

In an email to Aruba management, Warmenhoven explained why the dispute with Whitman was so important to Quattrone:

The issue is not Aruba. It is about the [Qatalyst] brand . . . . If word spreads that they were tossed from this deal because HP will not engage with them on any M&A transaction, that creates a big issue for them. . . . Frank
[Quattrone] wants to save his firm . . . . The relationship, or lack thereof, between [Qatalyst] and HP / Meg [Whitman] is now their focus.
Orr wondered "how much time we allow" before saying "sorry, [Qatalyst]. We need to protect our transaction. [W]e cannot worry about your brand!"

JX 437 at 1; see also JX 438 (Quattrone sending Warmenhoven what he described as a cordial rejection by Whitman of a social invitation as evidence that she had no bias against Qatalyst and was bluffing to gain leverage in the negotiations).

JX 440 at 1 (email from Orr to Aruba management).

Whitman finally spoke with Quattrone on January 29, 2015. She repeated the concerns she had relayed to Warmenhoven and again emphasized that "we cannot have [Qatalyst] as the primary representation for Aruba interacting with us and with our board." On February 1, Aruba formally retained Evercore for a contingent fee equal to 0.25% of the deal value.

JX 447 at 1 (email from Whitman to Quattrone dated January 28, 2015: "Will call you tomorrow.").

Whitman Dep. 127-28.

PTO ¶ 47; see also JX 5 (executed engagement letter); JX 232 (Aruba Board minutes authorizing Evercore engagement).

L. HP's Initial Proposal

By the time Whitman and Neri had dinner with Orr at the end of January 2015, HP had worked with Barclays to analyze a range of prices from $23 to $26.50 per share. Based on this analysis, HP anticipated making an "opening bid" of $24.00 and received board approval to go up to $25.00. After the dinner and Orr's enthusiastic response, HP revised its strategy. On January 31, Johansson called Orr to notify him that HP was preparing a written offer. Orr remained eager. He suggested accelerating the timeline and "getting a deal announced by [Aruba's] earnings on Feb 26." He offered that to achieve that timeline, Aruba "would respond as early as Monday/Tuesday of this week."

JX 398 at 1-2 (cover email for internal deck seeking HP Board approval); JX 805 at 12 (internal HP deck).

JX 455 at 1 (email from Orr to Aruba management and Qatalyst recounting call).

JX 454 (internal Barclays email summarizing Johansson's relay of the call).

Id.

Later that day, HP sent Aruba a written indication of interest for a cash transaction at $23.25 per share, for an aggregate valuation of $2.563 billion. The price per share represented a 40.2% premium to Aruba's closing price on the previous day and a 35.1% premium to the stock's thirty-day average price. The price exceeded Barclays' latest stand-alone discounted cash flow valuations of Aruba based on analyst estimates, which ranged from $17.47 to $22.61 per share. The price was seventy-five cents below the opening bid of $24.00 per share that HP had been considering at the beginning of the month. The offer was $3.80 per share below the low end of Barclays' most recent pro forma discounted cash flow valuations that included synergies, which valued Aruba at between $27.05 and $37.61 per share.

JX 452 at 3 ("Indicative Non-Binding Proposal").

Id. at 3-4.

JX 782 at 4 (Barclays deck).

Id.

M. Aruba Responds.

The Aruba Board initially met to consider HP's proposal on January 31, 2015. The directors decided to defer any detailed consideration of the proposal until after management presented revised projections and Evercore and Qatalyst had an opportunity to analyze them.

JX 461 at 2 (internal Evercore email relaying what Aruba's General Counsel anticipated to be the timeline of events).

On February 2, 2015, the Aruba Board met again. Management presented an updated version of the October Projections, prepared in the ordinary course of business, that reflected the Company's performance to date (the "February Projections"). Qatalyst reported that they had spoken with a sixth potential strategic partner who also was not interested in acquiring Aruba.

JX 233 (minutes); JX 910 at 3 (Aruba 8-K comparing October Projections and February Projections); Galvin Tr. 558-63 (discussing process of extending ordinary course six-month budgeting projections out to three years to create February Projections).

Proxy at 51.

While the Aruba Board was meeting, a new analyst report criticized the Company, and the stock price fell. Aruba's General Counsel forwarded the report to Evercore and Qatalyst, telling them that they should inform HP that "today's stock price does not reflect reality." She noted that Aruba was going to beat its guidance for the quarter, but that "no one knows that yet." Francis was similarly concerned that the negative analyst reports had depressed the stock price and created a buying opportunity for HP. But he also worried that HP would disengage if Aruba waited to release its quarterly results first and then negotiated from a place of strength; to get a deal done, it was "now or never."

JX 466 at 1-2 (internal Aruba email distributing report).

Id. at 1.

Id.

JX 470 at 1 (email from Francis to other Evercore bankers: "I am thinking about the analyst downgrades and if there [is] anything we can do.").

Id.

On February 4, 2015, the Aruba Board met again and received a presentation from Evercore on valuation. Using the February Projections, Evercore generated the following discounted cash flow valuation range for Aruba on a standalone basis:

JX 794 at 14 (Evercore deck).

Perpetuity Growth Rate

4.0%

4.3%

4.5%

4.8%

5.0%

WACC

10.5%

$23.97

$24.80

$25.71

$26.69

$27.76

11.0%

22.03

22.73

23.49

24.31

25.20

11.5%

20.35

20.95

21.60

22.29

23.03

12.0%

18.88

19.40

19.95

20.54

21.17

12.5%

17.58

18.03

18.51

19.01

19.56

Based on these figures, the Board authorized a counteroffer at $29 per share.

JX 234 (minutes); accord Warmenhoven Tr. 261 (testifying the Aruba Board came to the figure because "[w]e wanted to reaffirm that we thought there was great value there, meaning they should bid higher, but we felt like if we put a 3 in the first digit and started at 30, that they might conclude that's too big a gap to close and stop discussion").

Evercore conveyed the counteroffer to Barclays. Evercore emphasized that "now is not an opportune time for a sale, given the stock is at a 52-week low." Evercore also told Barclays that "[t]he low stock price reflects a misperception in the market that [Aruba] will miss its quarter. In fact, [Aruba] will beat consensus and have good guide." Barclays responded that the counteroffer was "not even within the realm of possibility."

JX 477 at 1 (Barclays email relaying counteroffer to HP).

Id.

Id.

N. HP Counters At Effectively The Same Price.

After receiving Aruba's counter, HP management caucused with its advisors. They prepared talking points which stated, contrary to HP's synergy-based valuations, that HP did "not have the ability to reach anywhere near" Aruba's counteroffer. The talking points also focused on timing, stressing that "[i]f we don't seize the opportunity now, there are many external pressure points that impact HP's ability to do a transaction with [Aruba] in the foreseeable future."

JX 484 at 1.

Id.

On February 7, 2015, Barclays told Evercore that any price increase would be on the scale of "quarters, not dollars." Evercore's reaction "was pretty constructive." Evercore "emphasized that [Aruba would] like to announce deal at or before the [Aruba] earnings announcement" because Aruba was "afraid stock runs like Ubiquiti's did which could make the deal more challenging from the [Aruba] perspective."

Proxy at 51.

JX 491 (email from Barclays to HP recounting exchange).

Id. Ubiquiti announced financial results on February 5, 2015 that beat the consensus estimates, and its stock rose by 14%. See JX 639 (Ubiquiti earnings transcript); JX 902 (Ubiquiti 8-K announcing results).

During the call with Barclays, Evercore also explained that Aruba's share repurchases had rendered outdated the share count contained in its public disclosures. Aruba in fact had 119.1 million shares outstanding, which was 4.5 million fewer than reported. Evercore told Barclays that HP should increase its price per share to account for the change.

JX 491; accord JX 488 at 4 (internal Evercore emails confirming change in shares outstanding and suggesting repurchases caused the change).

On February 9, 2015, Barclays recalculated the deal price based on the new share count. With fewer shares, the same aggregate consideration of $2.563 billion resulted in a price per share of $23.89. This was still below the opening bid of $24.00 per share that HP had contemplated before Whitman and Neri had dinner with Orr. That opening bid had equated to aggregate deal consideration of approximately $3 billion. With the lower share count, that same $3 billion enterprise value generated a price of $24.67 per share. HP decided to tell Aruba that its best and final bid was $24.67 per share, a figure that yielded the same enterprise value that HP originally intended to offer as its opening bid. Internally, HP described $24.67 as "the new $24.00," because the price merely adjusted for the change in Aruba's public share count.

JX 798 at 2 (Barclays slide entitled "Impact of New Share Count and B/S Data on Offer Price").

Id.

JX 497 (internal HP email from Johansson); accord JX 805 at 12 (timeline showing "02/08 - HP offer $24.00 and present as best and final. [Aruba] provide new shares outstanding and cash information supporting paying $24.67 at the same enterprise value.").

On February 9, 2015, Barclays communicated the counter of $24.67 per share to Evercore. The Aruba Board immediately met and authorized a counter at $25.00. Orr conveyed Aruba's ask of $25 per share to Neri. Orr also spoke to Whitman. Neither budged on price. Later that day, HP sent Aruba a "Revised Indicative Non-Binding Proposal" that proposed a cash price of $24.67 per share. HP described the bid as its "best and final offer." The proposal represented a 51.6% premium to Aruba's closing price on the previous day and a 48.9% premium to Aruba's thirty-day average trading price.

Proxy at 52.

Id.; accord JX 494 at 2 (email from Neri to Whitman summarizing conversation).

JX 496 at 1 (email from Francis to Aruba management transmitting revised proposal: "They did not move up just as Meg [Whitman] said to you.").

Id. at 3.

Id.

Id.

O. Aruba Accepts.

On February 10, 2015, the Aruba Board met to consider HP's revised proposal. Evercore, Orr, and Warmenhoven reported that the revised price resulted from considerable negotiation. They believed it represented HP's best and final offer. Qatalyst advised that it was unlikely that any other party would offer a higher price. The Board discussed "the recent weakness" in Aruba's share price and considered the alternative of continuing as a standalone company. The Board also considered standing firm on its ask for $25 per share. Ultimately, the Board decided to accept HP's offer of $24.67 per share.

JX 235 at 1-2 (minutes); accord Proxy at 52; Boutros Dep. 219-20 (describing lack of interest from other strategic bidders); Warmenhoven Dep. 104 (same).

JX 235 at 1-2; see also Warmenhoven Tr. 265-66 (testifying prospects of standing alone "were looking extremely challenging" because the "core market" was "going to zero growth" and Aruba was experiencing difficult "market conditions" and "competitive positioning").

JX 235 at 1-2; accord Proxy at 52; Warmenhoven Tr. 263.

On February 18, 2015, the Aruba Board considered whether to permit HP to speak with Orr and other members of Aruba's senior management about employment opportunities. No one disclosed to the Board that HP previously had made clear to Orr that they wanted him to run Aruba after the merger, or that Orr had told HP that he was willing to do so. The Board consented to the discussions and waived the non-solicitation provision in the confidentiality agreement with HP.

JX 237 (minutes).

Id.; accord Proxy at 52. See generally Orr Tr. 466-70 (discussing negotiation of new employment agreement with HP).

With approval from the Aruba Board in hand, HP conducted additional due diligence. Evercore approached this phase as an extended audition for future work from HP. In late February 2015, Francis reported to his partners about "a really interesting negotiating dinner at Meg's house Thursday night" and that "it was fun to be the only banker in the room to help both sides think through some issues." A senior Evercore banker responded "That's HUGE! Meg is going to be very active. . . . Would be a great new relationship." Francis bragged about having effectively acted as HP's advisor:

JX 505 at 1 (internal Evercore email).

Id.

Agreed... I think we made a pretty good impact from an advisory perspective, and she and I have known each other a long time socially through [P]rinceton events and when our kids were at Menlo school...please pardon the "pat on the back" nature of this comment, but after the meeting one of the people on our side said we had done a "masterful" job of taking [M]eg [Whitman] through the issues as if we were her advisor...let's hope that can help us get some traction in the future with her...
Rather than acting as a banker for Aruba, Evercore acted as a banker for the deal.

Id. (reproduced in full, ellipses in original); see also Reisenberg Dep. 248-54 (discussing JX 505).

P. The Deal Leaks.

On February 25, 2015, one day before Aruba was scheduled to announce its earnings, Bloomberg News ran a story on the merger. Internally at Qatalyst, Boutros speculated that HP had leaked the news so that Aruba's "results and subsequent stock price reaction won't be easy to measure." Aruba's stock price jumped from $18.37 to $22.24 on the news. An analyst issued a report positing that, in light of the synergies from the merger, a deal price of "$28 or a premium of 25% from today's close is reasonable [for Aruba]."

JX 866 (article).

JX 510 (internal Qatalyst email); see also Boutros Dep. 206-07 ("[N]ow the stock is going to trade based on takeover speculation and no more based on fundamentals, pure fundamentals. There is a lot of noise.").

Proxy at 53.

JX 152; accord JX 155 (JMP Securities report stating "[w]e believe the acquisition would be a logical step for HP" and anticipating "that Aruba's board would look for an acquisition price in the $23-$27 range").

On February 26, 2015, Aruba released its second quarter results. The Company beat analyst expectations and hit management's guidance. Analysts called the results "impressive" and "[b]etter-[t]han-[e]xpected." One praised Aruba for "[a]nother [s]trong [q]uarter." An analyst at Citi doubted that Aruba would be willing to sell "at prices near the current trading level" and suggested that Aruba would not take "less than $30/share."

JX 514 at 1, 3 (internal Barclays email discussing results).

JX 156 (Macquarie Research report).

JX 159 (William Blair report).

JX 157 (Jeffries report).

JX 168 at 3-4 (Citi report).

On February 27, 2015, Aruba's stock closed at $24.81 per share, above the merger price. That evening, the Aruba Board met to discuss how to respond. Qatalyst advised the Board that the deal still represented a 28% premium to Aruba's average trading price and a 44% premium to its thirty-day average price. Qatalyst also explained that the 10% price bump that Aruba enjoyed after its earnings release matched the price performance of peer firms after reporting similar results.

Proxy at 53.

JX 517 at 3 (Qatalyst board deck).

Id. at 6.

Despite Qatalyst's report on the market reaction to peer companies reporting similar results, the Aruba Board concluded that "the higher trading price was primarily being driven by market speculation of a transaction, and not by changes in the fundamentals of the business." The Board discussed renewing its request for $25 per share but rejected the idea in favor of using the stock price as leverage to insist on a lower termination fee and stronger deal terms. After the meeting, Aruba notified HP that it would not "be asking for a higher price."

Proxy at 53.

Id.

JX 520 (internal Barclays email).

Q. The Final Board Approvals

On February 28, 2015, the HP Board met to consider the definitive merger agreement. Barclays prepared a discounted cash flow analysis based on Aruba's "management case"—the February Projections. The analysis produced a valuation range of $26.20 to $33.64 per share for Aruba on a standalone basis. With synergies, Barclays valued Aruba at between $27.53 and $39.69 per share. Not surprisingly, Barclays opined that the deal price of $24.67 per share was fair to HP and its stockholders. The HP Board approved the merger agreement.

JX 806 at 14 (Barclays deck).

Id. at 15.

JX 238 at 1-3 (HP Board minutes).

On March 1, 2015, the Aruba Board convened to consider the definitive merger agreement. Both Qatalyst and Evercore gave valuation presentations. Qatalyst's discounted cash flow valuation ranged from $23.23 to $26.76 per share. Evercore's discounted cash flow valuation ranged from $21.12 to $29.78 per share. Both firms opined that the deal price of $24.67 per share was fair to Aruba and its stockholders. The Aruba Board approved the merger agreement.

JX 811 at 19 (Qatalyst deck).

JX 812 at 14 (Evercore deck).

Proxy at 53.

Getting the Aruba deal signed was a key step in Qatalyst's effort to get back in HP's good graces. Afterwards, Quattrone reported to his partners that Whitman had "asked [Orr] to pass along the message to us that there is now a path towards 'rehabilitation' of our relationship." Quattrone proposed to contact Whitman and "get her assurance that if we don't send the blast email" announcing Qatalyst's role in the deal, then Qatalyst would have "a clean slate going forward" with HP. His partners supported this approach, so Quattrone sent Whitman an email asking for a "clean slate." Quattrone also added "an appeal to your fairness," noting that "we have already been embarrassed and our business damaged by what has already occurred."

JX 521 at 1; see also Boutros Dep. 270 (testifying he understood Whitman to be amenable to "resolution of the issues she had and the feelings she had towards Qatalyst").

JX 521 at 2.

JX 522 at 2 ("[W]e do want to have a good relationship with you, and we are willing to explore alternatives to our normal course of business in marketing this deal, if I can have your assurance that by doing so, we will have a 'clean slate' with you and HP immediately going forward.").

Id. at 3. Aruba and HP announced the merger before Whitman responded. Qatalyst held off on publicity efforts pending her response. On March 3, 2015, Whitman told Quattrone he should "go ahead and do whatever communication feels right to you under the circumstances." Id. at 1-2. On March 4, Qatalyst sent out a blast announcing its role in the deal. JX 541 at 2. Whitman also told Quattrone that she was willing to "get together . . . and discuss the path forward." JX 522 at 2. The meeting eventually took place in October 2015. Afterwards, Quattrone sent Whitman a follow-up email which emphasized that he was "look[ing] forward to next steps in building a strong long-term relationship between our firms." JX 572 at 1-2.

R. Stockholder Approval

On March 2, 2015, Aruba and HP formally announced the merger. The final merger agreement (i) prohibited Aruba from soliciting competing offers and required the Aruba Board to continue to support the merger, subject to a fiduciary out and an out for an unsolicited superior proposal; (ii) included a $90 million termination fee; and (iii) provided a drop-dead date of February 28, 2016. Orr and Keerti Melkote, Aruba's co-founder and Chief Technology Officer, entered into voting agreements supporting the merger.

JX 907 (8-K announcing signing).

Id. at 3-4, 73-78.

Id. at 4.

No competing bidder emerged. On May 1, 2015, Aruba held a meeting of stockholders to consider the merger. Under Delaware law, unless a corporation's constitutive documents impose a higher voting requirement, a merger requires the approval of a majority of the voting power represented by the corporation's outstanding shares. Approximately 80.88% of Aruba's outstanding shares were represented at the meeting either in person or by proxy. Approximately 98% of those shares voted in favor of the merger. As a result, approximately 80% of the outstanding shares voted in favor of the merger, clearing the statutory requirement. The transaction closed on May 18, 2015.

Proxy at 1.

Aruba Networks, Inc., Current Report (Form 8-K) (May 1, 2015). Although the parties did not submit this filing as an exhibit, the Delaware Supreme Court has taken judicial notice of public filings in an appraisal case and relied on them for the truth of their contents. See, e.g., DFC, 172 A.3d at 351 n.7.

JX 914 at 2 (8-K announcing closing).

S. This Litigation

At the effective time of the merger, petitioners Verition Partners Master Fund Ltd. and Verition Multi-Strategy Master Fund Ltd. (jointly, "Verition") owned in the aggregate 2,288,234 shares of Aruba's common stock. Verition filed this appraisal proceeding on August 28, 2015. The parties engaged in discovery for nearly two years. During discovery, Aruba's counsel took several aggressive and credibility-impairing positions.

See PTO ¶¶ 11, 17.

On May 5, 2016, Verition noticed Whitman's deposition. Aruba promptly filed for a protective order seeking to limit the deposition to three hours. Aruba asserted that Whitman had "limited involvement in HP's acquisition of Aruba," that "Aruba and HP are aware of nothing in the vast discovery in this case to suggest there were any communications between Ms. Whitman and any representative of Aruba negotiating pricing terms of the Aruba deal," and that her view towards Qatalyst was immaterial because it "has no bearing on the fair value of Aruba as a stand-alone company." While perhaps technically correct, these representations created a misleading picture of Whitman's involvement. Verition submitted exhibits in response to the motion that made the assertions look silly, and the evidence at trial subsequently reinforced their misleading character. I denied the motion for protective order and required Whitman to testify from day to day until the deposition was completed.

Dkt. 56 at 11-13 (motion opening brief).

Dkt. 65.

The parties next clashed when Verition moved to strike aspects of the report of Kevin Dages, Aruba's valuation expert. In his report, Dages relied on an email exchange between Aruba management and the Company's lawyers at Wilson Sonsini Goodrich & Rosati, P.A. for information about stock-based compensation. During Dages's deposition, it became evident that Aruba had withheld the communication as privileged. Dages then attempted, unpersuasively, to suggest the citation had been a typographical error and that he had actually drawn the information from a different source that Aruba had produced. Complicating matters further, Verition showed that, during the deposition of another witness (Galvin), Aruba's lawyers engaged in substantive discussions about the email with the witness during a break. At the hearing, I expressed significant concern about Aruba's discovery conduct, but I concluded that I could address the matter by weighing the evidence rather than by striking a portion of Dages's report.

See Dkt. 125 (transcript and rulings on motion to strike).

Verition dug deeper. Aruba had served a vast privilege log containing 20,000 entries and spanning 1,462 pages. Verition confirmed that at least 529 entries asserted privilege for communications about Aruba's projections and stock-based compensation. Those communications took place during the preparation of Aruba's proxy statement, and Wilson Sonsini lawyers were copied on the communications as part of the team, but the communications were not privileged. Aruba had asserted privilege for those communications simply because a lawyer appeared on the document. After Aruba produced them, Verition renewed its motion to strike. This time, I found that Verition had shown a broader pattern of problematic conduct that had prejudiced Verition. It was too late to remedy the prejudice through other means, and I therefore struck the portions of Dages's report relating to stock-based compensation.

See Dkt. 153 (transcript and rulings on renewed motion to strike).

Trial took place from December 13-15, 2016. Through no fault of the parties, the post-trial proceedings became protracted. The parties initially completed post-trial briefing by March 30, 2017, and post-trial argument was scheduled for May 17. I postponed the hearing once it became clear that the Delaware Supreme Court's forthcoming decision in DFC likely would have a significant effect on the legal landscape. The Delaware Supreme Court issued its decision on August 1. Both sides submitted supplemental briefs addressing the implications of DFC, and post-trial argument took place on September 29.

While this matter was under submission, on December 14, 2017, the Delaware Supreme Court issued its decision in Dell. I invited the parties to provide supplemental submissions addressing the implications of Dell and the extent to which attributes of the market for Aruba's stock resembled the attributes that the Delaware Supreme Court emphasized in Dell. The parties filed their submissions on January 26, 2018.

II. LEGAL ANALYSIS

Delaware's appraisal statute "allows stockholders who perfect their appraisal rights to receive 'fair value' for their shares as of the merger date instead of the merger consideration."

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *1.

[T]he purpose of an appraisal is not to make sure that the petitioners get the highest conceivable value that might have been procured had every domino fallen out of the company's way; rather, it is to make sure that they receive fair compensation for their shares in the sense that it reflects what they deserve to receive based on what would fairly be given to them in an arm's-length transaction.
Put differently, "[t]he issue in an appraisal is not whether a negotiator has extracted the highest possible bid. Rather, the key inquiry is whether the dissenters got fair value and were not exploited."

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *24.

The trial court's "ultimate goal in an appraisal proceeding is to determine the 'fair or intrinsic value' of each share on the closing date of the merger." To accomplish this task, "the court should first envisage the entire pre-merger company as a 'going concern,' as a standalone entity, and assess its value as such." "Because the court 'strives to value the corporation itself as distinguished from a specific fraction of its shares as they may exist in the hands of a particular shareholder,' the court should not apply a minority discount when there is a controlling stockholder." The court should exclude "any synergies or other value expected from the merger giving rise to the appraisal proceeding." "[O]nce the total standalone value is determined, the court awards each petitioning stockholder his pro rata portion of this total . . . plus interest."

Id. at *13 (quoting Cavalier Oil Corp. v. Hartnett, 564 A.2d 1137, 1142-43 (Del. 1989)).

Id. (quoting Cavalier Oil, 564 A.2d at 1144).

Id. (quoting Cavalier Oil, 564 A.2d at 1144).

Glob. GT LP v. Golden Telecom, Inc. (Golden Telecom Trial), 993 A.2d 497, 507 (Del. Ch. 2010) (Strine, V.C.), aff'd, 11 A.3d 214 (Del. 2010); accord DFC, 172 A.3d at 368 ("[B]y valuing the company on its value as a 'going concern,' the [Delaware Supreme] Court [in Cavalier Oil] seemed to require the excision of any value that might be attributable to expected synergies by a buyer."); M.P.M. Enters., Inc. v. Gilbert, 731 A.2d 790, 797 (Del. 1999) ("[S]ection 262(h) requires that the Court of Chancery discern the going concern value of the company irrespective of the synergies involved in a merger.").

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *14.

When seeking to prove fair value, parties may introduce "proof of value by any techniques or methods which are generally considered acceptable in the financial community and otherwise admissible in court." "[T]he statute assigns the Court of Chancery the duty to consider the relevant methods of valuation argued by the parties and then determine which method (and inputs), or combination of methods, yields the most reliable determination of value." "But, whatever route it chooses, the trial court must justify its methodology (or methodologies) according to the facts of the case and relevant, accepted financial principles." "Although the Court of Chancery has broad discretion to make findings of fact, those findings of fact have to be grounded in the record and reliable principles of corporate finance and economics."

Weinberger v. UOP, Inc., 457 A.2d 701, 713 (Del. 1983).

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *15 n.105.

Id. at *15.

In this case, "the relevant methods of valuation argued by the parties" are (i) Aruba's unaffected market price, (ii) the deal price, and (iii) competing discounted cash flow analyses. The degree of emphasis that the parties have placed on these methodologies has evolved. During discovery and at trial, both sides focused on their experts' discounted cash flow valuations. As the number of opinions that focused on the deal price mounted, the respondent placed greater emphasis on that metric, and the petitioners responded by attacking the process that led to the deal. After DFC, the respondent stressed a combination of the unaffected market price and the deal price. After Dell, the respondent redoubled its emphasis on the combination of the unaffected market price and the deal price.

A. The Unaffected Market Price

The Delaware Supreme Court's recent decisions in DFC and Dell teach that if a company's shares trade in a market having attributes consistent with the assumptions underlying a traditional version of the semi-strong form of the efficient capital markets hypothesis, then the unaffected trading price provides evidence of the fair value of a proportionate interest in the company as a going concern. That evidence is more reliable than the single estimate of any one individual, be he a knowledgeable market participant, corporate insider, valuation professional, or trial judge. Under this standard, Aruba's unaffected market price provides persuasive evidence of fair value.

By "traditional," I mean a framing of the efficient capital markets hypothesis consistent with Eugene Fama's seminal work and its baseline Chicago-school assumptions. See Eugene F. Fama, Efficient Capital Markets: A Review of Theory and Empirical Work, 25 J. Fin. 383 (1970).
At the trial court level in Dell, I cited some points of entry into a significant and growing body of literature that raises question about the assumptions undergirding the traditional model, which suggest a need for greater nuance. See In re Appraisal of Dell, Inc. (Dell Trial Fair Value), 2016 WL 3186538, at *25 n.16 (Del. Ch. May 31, 2016), rev'd in pertinent part sub nom. Dell, Inc. v. Magnetar Glob. Event Driven Master Fund Ltd,A.3d, 2017 WL 6375829 (Del. Dec. 14, 2017). In the legal field, much of this work has responded to the United States Supreme Court's relatively highlevel framing of the efficient capital markets hypothesis as the cornerstone for using the fraudonthemarket theory to create a presumption of reliance in securities fraud actions. See Basic Inc. v. Levinson, 485 U.S. 224, 24142, 24344, 246 (1988). The field of behavioral economics has yielded particularly powerful insights. See, e.g., Donald C. Langevoort, Theories, Assumptions, and Securities Regulation: Market Efficiency Revisited, 140 U. Pa. L. Rev. 851 (1992); Larry E. Ribstein, Fraud on a Noisy Market, 10 Lewis & Clark L. Rev. 137 (2006); Jeff Schwartz, Fairness, Utility, and Market Risk, 89 Or. L. Rev. 175 (2010). Noise trading theory and chaos theory have yielded additional insights. See, e.g., Lawrence A. Cunningham, From Random Walks to Chaotic Crashes: The Linear Genealogy of the Efficient Capital Markets Hypothesis, 62 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 546 (1994); Lawrence A. Cunningham, Capital Market Theory, Mandatory Disclosure, and Price Discovery, 51 Wash & Lee L. Rev. 843 (1994); Andrei Schleifer & Lawrence H. Summers, The Noise Trader Approach to Finance, 4 J. Econ. Persp. 19 (1990).
Perhaps future appraisal litigants will retain experts on market efficiency, as is common in federal securities actions, and maybe future appraisal decisions will consider subtler aspects of the efficient capital markets hypothesis. This decision does not provide any opportunity for doing so. In its supplemental submissions on the implications of Dell and DFC, the petitioners alluded to potential objections to the Delaware Supreme Court's framing of the efficient capital markets hypothesis, but they did not develop those objections in any meaningful way. Absent a casespecific expert opinion supported by credible evidence and the weight of socialscience research, I do not believe a trial judge has the flexibility to disregard the Delaware Supreme Court's framing of the efficient capital markets hypothesis.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *17; DFC, 172 A.3d at 369-70.

1. The Efficient Capital Markets Hypothesis

Both Dell and DFC endorse the efficient capital markets hypothesis and its predictions about the reliability of market prices. In DFC, the Delaware Supreme Court stated that "real world transaction prices can be the most probative evidence of fair value even through appraisal's particular lens." The high court observed that "[m]arket prices are typically viewed superior to other valuation techniques because, unlike, e.g., a single person's discounted cash flow model, the market price should distill the collective judgment of the many based on all the publicly available information about a given company and the value of its shares." The court added that, from the perspective of economics, when the subject company's shares are "widely traded on a public market based upon a rich information base," then the fair value of a proportionate interest in the company as a going concern would "likely be best reflected by the prices at which [the] shares were trading as of the merger."

Id. at 369-70.

Id. at 367.

In Dell, the Delaware Supreme Court stated that "the price produced by an efficient market is generally a more reliable assessment of fair value than the view of a single analyst, especially an expert witness who caters her valuation to the litigation imperatives of a well-heeled client." The court explained that, when the market for a company's stock has attributes associated with efficient trading, the stock price

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *17.

reflects the judgments of many stockholders about the company's future prospects, based on public filings, industry information, and research conducted by equity analysts. In these circumstances, a mass of investors quickly digests all publicly available information about a company, and in trading the company's stock, recalibrates its price to reflect the market's adjusted, consensus valuation of the company.
The court concluded that, when the market for a company's shares has the requisite attributes, the stock price is "likely a possible proxy for fair value."

Id. (internal quotation marks and footnote omitted).

Id. at *1 (reversing trial court's fair value determination because, among other reasons, "[h]ere, the trial court gave no weight to Dell's stock price because it found its market to be inefficient. But the evidence suggests that the market for Dell's shares was actually efficient and, therefore, likely a possible proxy for fair value.").

Under Dell and DFC, the critical question is whether the market for the subject company's shares has attributes associated with market efficiency. In Dell, the high court described the relevant attributes as follows: "A market is more likely efficient, or semi- strong efficient, if it has many stockholders; no controlling stockholder; highly active trading; and if information about the company is widely available and easily disseminated to the market."

Id. at *17 (internal quotation marks omitted).

In both Dell and DFC, the Delaware Supreme Court found that the market for the subject company's shares had the necessary attributes. The Dell decision described the market for Dell's stock as follows:

Dell's stock traded on the NASDAQ under the ticker symbol DELL. The Company's market capitalization of more than $20 billion ranked it in the top third of the S&P 500. Dell had a deep public float and was actively traded as more than 5% of Dell's shares were traded each week. The stock had a bid-ask spread of approximately 0.08%. It was also widely covered by equity analysts, and its share price quickly reflected the market's view on breaking developments. Based on these metrics, the record suggests the market for Dell stock was semi-strong efficient, meaning that the market's digestion and assessment of all publicly available information concerning Dell was quickly impounded into the Company's stock price. For example, on January 14, 2013, Dell's stock jumped 9.8% within a minute of Bloomberg breaking the news of the Company's take-private talks, and the stock closed up 13% from the day prior—on a day the S&P as a whole fell 0.1%.
The DFC decision described the market for DFC's stock in similar, albeit more abbreviated, terms:
DFC's shares were traded on the NASDAQ exchange from 2005 until the merger. Throughout its history as a public company, the record suggests that DFC never had a controlling stockholder, it had a deep public float of 39.6 million shares, and, it had an average daily trading volume just short of one million shares. DFC's share price moved sharply in reaction to information
about the company's performance, the industry, and the overall economy . . . .
The high court later noted that "DFC's stock was listed on a major U.S. exchange, traded actively, and had moved sharply over the years when the company was poised for growth or facing dimming prospects."

Id. at *3 (footnotes omitted).

Id. at 372.

In neither case did an expert render an opinion on market efficiency, as is common in federal securities law actions when a plaintiff seeks to invoke the presumption of reliance associated with the fraud-on-the-market theory. Nor was all of the market evidence part of the trial record. In DFC, the Delaware Supreme Court cited record evidence for some of the information about DFC's stock profile; it drew other information from DFC's public filings with the SEC or from an expert report addressing valuation issues. In Dell, the Delaware Supreme Court similarly drew much of the market-related information from public filings with the SEC or from an expert report addressing valuation issues.

See, e.g., Amgen Inc. v. Conn. Ret. Plans & Tr. Funds, 568 U.S. 455, 471 n.6 (2013) (noting trial court relying on "unchallenged expert report . . . expressly found that the market for Amgen's stock was efficient"); IBEW Local 98 Pension Fund v. Best Buy Co., Inc., 818 F.3d 775, 779 (8th Cir. 2016) (noting "plaintiffs submitted a report by their expert" to support their "motion for class certification [which] relied on Basic's fraud-on-the-market presumption"); Schleicher v. Wendt, 618 F.3d 679, 682 (7th Cir. 2010) ("A financial economist concluded, in an expert report that the district judge credited, that the market for Conseco's shares was efficient . . . and that investors therefore can use the fraud-on-the-market doctrine as a replacement for person-specific proof of reliance and causation."). See generally 7AA Charles Alan Wright, Arthur R. Miller & Mary Kay Kane, Federal Practice and Procedure § 1781.1 (3d ed. 2005).

See DFC, 172 A.3d at 352-53 (citing analyst reports and petitioners' and respondent's expert reports on valuation).

See Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *3 nn.9-15 (citing public filings with SEC and report of Dell's valuation expert).

In this case, as in Dell and DFC, no expert offered an opinion, pro or con, on whether the subject company's shares traded in an efficient market. During trial, the parties did not emphasize the attributes of the market for Aruba's common stock. Nevertheless, information drawn from sources comparable to those the Delaware Supreme Court used in Dell and DFC indicates that the market for Aruba's common stock had basic attributes consistent with what the high court found sufficient in those decisions:

• Aruba's shares traded on the NASDAQ through the date of the merger under the symbol ARUN.

• Aruba did not have a controlling stockholder.

• Aruba made public filings in compliance with the disclosure requirements imposed by federal securities laws.

• Thirty-three securities analysts covered Aruba.
• Aruba's weekly trading volume was 9.5 million shares or 8.7% of total shares outstanding.

• Aruba's bid-ask spread was 0.055%.

See Marcus Tr. 59 (Verition's expert testifying that "the stock was trading well"); Marcus Dep. 198-99 (Verition's expert testifying that Aruba was "actively traded" as contrasted with "a company that, you know, is thinly traded" and where "there might be some efficiency issues"); see also Aruba Networks, Inc., Notification of Removal from Listing and/or Registration Under Section 12(b) of the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 (Form 25) (May 19, 2015).

See Marcus Opening Report Ex. 3-1 ("Summary of Analyst Price Targets"); Marcus Tr. 59 (Verition's expert noting that "[t]here was lots of analyst coverage"); Marcus Dep. 198-99 (Verition's expert noting that Aruba had "30 plus analysts covering them").

JX 164 (BMO Capital Markets report containing trading statistics); see also Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *3 n.10 (citing 5 Alan R. Bromberg et al., Bromberg & Lowenfels on Securities Fraud § 7:484 (2d ed. June 2017 Update) ("Turnover measured by average weekly trading of 2% or more of the outstanding shares would justify a strong presumption that the market for the security is an efficient one.")).

See Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *3 (stating that Dell's spread of approximately 0.08% was indicative of market efficiency).

The following table compares the numerical attributes of Aruba's common stock with the comparable attributes for the subject companies in Dell and DFC.

DFC

Dell

Aruba

Market Cap.

$375 million

$20 billion

$2.5 billion

Shares in publicfloat

37.5 million

1.45 billion

104 million

Public float as %of outstanding

95%

85%

96%

Bid-ask spread

0.098%

0.08%

0.055%

# of analysts

10

33

33

Given these attributes, Aruba's stock price is "likely a possible proxy for fair value."

Id. at *1; see also DFC, 172 A.3d 367-68.

In addition, as in Dell, there is evidence that the Company's stock price reacted quickly to the release of news about the Company.

See, e.g., JX 245; Dkt. 162 at 13 (Petitioners' Opening Post-Trial Brief containing stock price chart); Dkt. 188 Ex. A (publicly available stock-price data for Aruba & S&P 500).

• When Aruba announced Project Greyhound after the market closed on August 26, 2014, the stock price rose by 5% the next day, closing at $21.26 on a day when the S&P 500 was stagnant.

• When Aruba announced its first quarter fiscal year 2015 earnings after the market closed on November 20, 2014, Aruba's stock price dropped by 14% on November 21 on a day when the S&P 500 was up 0.5%.

• When Bloomberg News reported that HP was in talks to buy Aruba on February 25, 2015, Aruba's stock price rose 21%. The news came out at 3:02 p.m. and, within one minute, Aruba's stock price had increased 12.7%. By 3:11 p.m., the price had increased to $22.86, before closing at $22.24 at 4 p.m. The same day, the S&P 500 decreased 0.1%.

• When Aruba announced its second quarter fiscal year 2015 earnings after the market closed on February 26, 2015, the stock price increased the next day by 9.7%. That same day, the S&P 500 decreased by 0.3%.

• When the merger was confirmed and the merger price of $24.67 announced on March 2, 2015, the stock price decreased slightly to close at $24.65.
Obviously, these are anecdotal observations and not event studies, but they compare favorably with the Dell court's observation that Dell's share price "quickly reflected the market's view on breaking developments," citing, as an example, that "on January 14, 2013, Dell's stock jumped 9.8% within a minute of Bloomberg breaking the news of the Company's take-private talks, and the stock closed up 13% from the day prior—on a day the S&P 500 as a whole fell 0.1%." Similar evidence in this case reinforces the conclusion that Aruba's stock price leading up to the merger is "likely a possible proxy for fair value."

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *3.

Id. at *1; see also DFC, 172 A.3d at 367-68.

2. Evidence Of Market Mispricing

The petitioners dispute the reliability of Aruba's market price in this case, contending that HP timed its acquisition to take advantage of a trough in the market. They rely on a range of authorities, including the Delaware Supreme Court's decision in Glassman v. Unocal Exploration Corp., which stated that, if an acquisition "was timed to take advantage of a depressed market, or a low point in the company's cyclical earnings, or to precede an anticipated positive development, the appraised value may be adjusted to account for those factors."

777 A.2d 242, 248 (Del. 2001).

The petitioners argue that the market mispricing in this case began after the Company reported positive quarterly results in May 2014. Revenue exceeded both management guidance and Wall Street consensus estimates, but the Company reported a gross margin of 70.5%, below the consensus estimate of 72% and Aruba's "longstanding target of 71-73%." The miss triggered harsh analyst coverage, and Aruba's stock price dropped 12.11% on the news, declining from $20.06 to $17.63. As evidence of the market overreaction, the petitioners rely on internal assessments by Aruba management.

See JX 47 (Barclays report); JX 48 (Janney Capital Markets report).

JX 47 at 1.

JX 259 at 2-3 (email collecting analyst coverage).

See JX 260 at 5-6 (email thread among management discussing market reaction); JX 267 (Orr reporting to the Aruba Board: "[W]e, as an executive team, are finally sick of wall st discrediting our tremendous come back in revenue growth because they said we are not as profitable as Ubiquiti (give me a break!)."); JX 269 at 2 (Orr email to Galvin: "Between you and me, if we do all these and our stock price stays $13-20, you and I fail miserably. I don't know why we are doing all these [sic] tough stuff. I really don't."); see also Warmenhoven Tr. 235 ("It was very frustrating for the management team, I must say. I mean, in -- in fiscal year 2014, they had 20 percent year-over-year growth, and we were delivering everything to the street, and the stock really didn't move.").

To address the gross margin issue, Aruba management developed Project Greyhound. Management undertook the project because the "Company value [was] not adequately reflected in [the] stock price." Aruba announced record results in August 2014 and simultaneously announced the implementation of Project Greyhound. Analysts had mixed reactions. Aruba's stock price rose by roughly 9%, from $20.24 to $22.01. As evidence of continued mispricing, the petitioners rely on Aruba management's internal view that it would take "a couple of quarters" after the implementation of Project Greyhound for Wall Street to credit the results.

See JX 280 (internal Aruba deck on Project Greyhound).

JX 273 at 2 (draft internal talking points); see also Orr Tr. 486 (suggesting Project Greyhound was motivated, in part, by sense stock price "does not reflect what we believe is our commitment to deliver to what the analysts and the investors want us to do"); Galvin Tr. 597-98 (acknowledging Aruba undertook Project Greyhound, in part, because "we did have pressure from Wall Street to improve what we were dropping to the bottom line"); id. at 600 (agreeing "Greyhound was initiated because there was a perception that the company value was not adequately reflected in the stock price").

JX 828 (press release announcing results).

Compare JX 59 at 2 and JX 62 at 1 with JX 61 at 1 and JX 64 at 1. See also JX 309 at 7 (Aruba Board deck summarizing analyst reports and noting that fifteen analysts increased their target price).

JX 245.

Galvin Tr. 602-03 (testifying that, with respect to Project Greyhound, "there were things that would play out over time"); Galvin Dep. 82 (agreeing "that it would take a couple of quarters after announcement of the initiation of the transformation to see the real results and have the results on Wall Street").

The petitioners contend that matters worsened in November 2014. That month, Aruba reported on an "outstanding quarter" that included "[r]ecord revenues" that exceeded "the top end of [its] guidance range" and improved margins thanks to Project Greyhound. But Aruba also announced a range of revenue guidance for the upcoming quarter that was 1% lower at the midpoint than the pre-announcement analyst consensus. Analysts fixated on the lowered guidance. Aruba's stock dropped by 14%, closing at $18.82. As evidence of the market overreaction, the petitioners rely on the internal assessments of Aruba management, who explained that they lowered guidance simply to be prudent and not because of any change in the business dynamics. They also rely on internal assessments by the HP deal team, who viewed Aruba's strong results as validating their internal business case and saw the price drop as an opportunity to buy Aruba at a discount.

JX 638 at 3 (transcript from Aruba earnings call).

JX 363 (internal HP email summarizing the earnings announcement).

JX 245.

JX 638 at 13 (Galvin stating Aruba was "just being prudent in a mixed environment" and "[n]ot getting ahead of our skis"); see also JX 355 at 1 (email from Galvin to Aruba Board: "our guide is shaping up to be more cautious than our strong results").

See JX 357 at 1 (Neri: "We told our story and we were on point."); JX 360 (email from HP's Senior Vice President of Corporate Development: "I thought the results were pretty good. . . . They blew past the revenue expectations for the quarter. But they guided soft, below consensus."); JX 780 at 2 (internal HP deck discussing Aruba's November earnings announcement and commenting that "[t]he softer guidance did not cause us to change our financial model")

See JX 357 at 1 (internal email among members of the HP deal team: "They are down 8% after hours though because of guidance below consensus for this quarter (although it looks like the range of guidance is still within expectations). Good time to pull the trigger and snap them up I would say."); Hardegree Dep. 193 (observing that the stock price drop "probably did, on balance" put HP "in a more tacti[cally] advantaged position").

After Dell and DFC, I do not believe that the petitioners' evidence provides any basis to question the integrity of Aruba's pre-announcement market price as an indicator of fair value. As a threshold matter, it is not clear that Glassman has continuing relevance to a widely held, publicly traded entity. Although the Delaware Supreme Court in Glassman did not limit its comments about the appraisal standard to any particular context, the case involved a short-form merger in which a controlling stockholder eliminated the minority. Aruba was not a controlled company, and the market for its shares exhibited the attributes that the Delaware Supreme Court in Dell and DFC found sufficient to give effect to the implications of the semi-strong form of the efficient capital markets hypothesis.

See 777 A.2d at 243 ("In this appeal, we consider the fiduciary duties owed by a parent corporation to the subsidiary's minority stockholders in the context of a 'short-form' merger.").

In Dell, at the trial level, I found "widespread and compelling evidence of a valuation gap between the market's perception and the Company's operative reality." As I viewed the evidence, "[t]he gap was driven by (i) analysts' focus on short-term, quarter-by-quarter results and (ii) the Company's nearly $14 billion investment in its transformation, which had not yet begun to generate the anticipated results." In making this finding, I relied on record evidence indicating that (i) Michael Dell and other members of management valued the company at levels significantly above the market price in light of its ongoing transformation and a related cost-savings initiative, (ii) the financial advisors to the special committee running the sale process generated valuations implying values for the company that far exceeded its market price, and (iii) Mr. Dell and the special committee's advisors (including two financial advisors and a consulting firm) believed that the valuation gap existed because the company's stockholders were focused on the short-term rather than the long-term.

Dell Trial Fair Value, 2016 WL 3186538, at *32.

Id.

See id. at *1-2, *34.

See id. at *34.

See id. at *34-35 (citing JX 96; JX 110; JX 137; JX 170; JX 226; JX 344; JX 530).

On appeal, the Delaware Supreme Court held that, in light of the attributes of the market for Dell's shares and the implications of the semi-strong form of the efficient capital markets hypothesis, my reliance on the views of these knowledgeable insiders constituted an abuse of discretion. I had cited various analyst reports as evidence of the contrast between external views and the insiders' assessments. The high court found that the analyst reports showed "just the opposite: analysts scrutinized Dell's long-range outlook when evaluating the Company and setting price targets, and the market was capable of accounting for Dell's recent mergers and acquisitions and their prospects in its valuation of the Company." More broadly, the Delaware Supreme Court held that my finding "ignored the efficient market hypothesis long endorsed by this court." The high court found that "[t]he apparent efficiency of Dell's pre-signing stock market and the long-term approach of its analysts undermine concerns of a 'valuation gap.'"

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *19 ("In short, the record does not adequately support the Court of Chancery's conclusion that the market for Dell's stock was inefficient and that a valuation gap in the Company's market trading price existed in advance of the lengthy market check, an error that contributed to the trial court's decision to disregard the deal price.").

Id. at *16 & n.112 (citing analyst reports discussing Dell's M&A activity).

Id. at *17 (citing DFC, 172 A.3d 346). Legal historians can debate how longstanding that endorsement had been. See Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc. (Technicolor II), 684 A.2d 289, 301 (Del. 1996) (observing, in context of appraisal of publicly traded company following arm's-length deal, that "the market price of shares may not be representative of fair value" (internal quotation marks omitted)); Rapid-Am. Corp. v. Harris, 603 A.2d 796, 806 (Del. 1992) (describing the Court of Chancery's rejection of market value in Chicago Corp. v. Munds, 172 A. 452 (Del. Ch. 1934), and observing that "Munds' succinct evaluation of the market has lost none of its luster"); see also Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc. (Technicolor I), 542 A.2d 1182, 1187 n.8 (Del. 1988) ("Information and insight not communicated to the market may not be reflected in stock prices; thus, minority shareholders being cashed out may be deprived of part of the true investment value of their shares. The issue we are addressing is not the manipulation of the transaction, nor the suppression or misstatement of material information by insiders defrauding the market. Instead, we recognize that the majority may have insight into their company's future based primarily on bits and pieces of nonmaterial information that have value as a totality." (citations omitted)). See generally Implicit Minority Discount, supra, at 8 ("Delaware appraisal law has never been particularly friendly to the idea that stock market prices always accurately represent a proportional share of the value of the enterprise as a going concern."). If the lens is broadened to take in fiduciary duty cases, the longstanding nature of the endorsement becomes even more debatable. See, e.g., Unitrin, Inc. v. Am. Gen. Corp., 651 A.2d 1361, 1384 (Del. 1995) (reaffirming the Delaware Supreme Court's recognition of the threat of substantive coercion, defined as "the risk that shareholders will mistakenly accept an underpriced offer because they disbelieve management's representations of intrinsic value" (internal quotation marks and citation omitted)); Paramount Commc'ns, Inc. v. Time Inc., 571 A.2d 1140, 1150 n.12 (Del. 1989) ("Thus, we endorse the Chancellor's conclusion that it is not a breach of faith for directors to determine that the present stock market price of shares is not representative of true value or that there may indeed be several market values for any corporation's stock."); Smith v. Van Gorkom, 488 A.2d 858, 875-76 (Del. 1985) ("[I]n the absence of other sound valuation information, the fact of a premium [over market price] alone does not provide an adequate basis upon which to assess the fairness of an offering price. . . . Using market price as a basis for concluding that the premium adequately reflected the true value of the Company was a clearly faulty, indeed fallacious, premise, as the defendants' own evidence demonstrates."), overruled on other grounds by Gantler v. Stephens, 965 A.2d 695 (Del. 2009). See generally Bernard Black & Reinier Kraakman, Delaware's Takeover Law: The Uncertain Search for Hidden Value, 96 Nw. U. L. Rev. 521 (2002) (surveying Delaware takeover decisions and explaining their reliance on a theory of hidden value inconsistent with the efficient capital markets hypothesis). If the management-buyout in Dell had instead been an unsolicited, all-cash, all-shares offer at the deal price, I have no doubt that the Dell board of directors could have defended against that offer based on management's belief in the considerably greater long-term value of the company. See Air Prods. & Chems., Inc. v. Airgas, Inc., 16 A.3d 48, 108-13 (Del. Ch. 2011).
Setting temporal characterizations aside, I do not question the authority of the Delaware Supreme Court to endorse a traditional framing of the efficient capital markets hypothesis as a method of assessing the reliability of market prices in appraisal proceedings. Once the Delaware Supreme Court has done so, the obligation of a trial judge is to adhere to that endorsement and its implications.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *25.

In this case, I regard the petitioners' evidence of market mispricing as considerably weaker than what I abused my discretion by crediting in Dell. The evidence in Dell involved the company's likelihood of successfully completing a corporate transformation after spending $14 billion to acquire eleven businesses over three years. The evidence in this case concerns revenue guidance for an upcoming quarter and the implications of a cost-cutting effort (Project Greyhound). As in Dell, the analyst reports show that market observers were assessing these variables. As in Dell, there is no indication that management did not try to communicate forthrightly with the market. In contrast to Dell, the internal concerns that Orr and other members of management expressed in this case lacked the degree of analytical and valuation-based support that accompanied the critiques by Mr. Dell, his management team, and the special committee's advisors. In this case, the internal concerns seem more like reactive expressions of frustration. To reiterate, the evidence in Dell was insufficient to support my finding regarding the existence of a valuation gap. Indeed, the Delaware Supreme Court regarded it as the equivalent of no evidence at all. The weaker evidence here is insufficient to undermine the reliability of Aruba's unaffected market price.

See id. at *17 ("The record before us provides no rational, factual basis for such a 'valuation gap.'"); id. ("There is also no evidence in the record that investors were 'myopic' or shortsighted."). The senior tribunal believed that, without any evidence, I "presumed" that "'investor myopia' and hangover from the Company's 'nearly $14 billion investment in its transformation, which had not yet begun to generate the anticipated results,' produced a 'valuation gap'" and this "presumption contributed to the trial court's decision to assign no weight to Dell's stock price or deal price." Id. at *16 (quoting Dell Trial Fair Value, 2016 WL 3186538, at *32, *34).
I did not use the term "presumption," and I regret that poor drafting on my part seemingly created the impression that I had applied a presumption of some sort. I personally thought I was relying on record evidence that took the form of contemporaneous assessments by knowledgeable insiders about investors' growing shortterm focus and a divergence between the trading price and indications of fundamental value. See Dell Trial Fair Value, 2016 WL 3186538, at *2 (discussing divergence between management's internal valuation and the market price, including Mr. Dell's testimony that the market just "didn't get" Dell (Tr. 409) and his belief that, in spite of Dell's transformation, "Dell [was] still seen as a PC business" (JX 44 at 1)); id. (discussing management's hiring consultants to address market misperception (JX 46 at 1)); id. at *4 (discussing Mr. Dell's assessment of divergence between shortterm results and longterm value (JX 109 at 7; JX 110 at 1)); id. (discussing management's reports to board regarding shortterm challenges and need to "sacrifice short term results" to create longterm value (JX 96 at 2; JX 97 at 16)); id. at *5 (discussing JP Morgan report explaining that Dell's recent earnings misses "have put investors in a 'wait and see mode' with increased focus on quarterbyquarter execution and improved visibility" (JX 137 at 7)); id. at *7 (discussing views of JPMorgan and Goldman Sachs regarding factors contributing to low market valuation that appeared disconnected from fundamentals (JX 170)); id. at *9 (discussing Mr. Dell's reasons for proposing a goingprivate transaction including that his initiatives would be "poorly received by the public markets" and that they "could best be accomplished in an environment without quarterly earnings pressure" (JX 231 at 2)); id. at *19 (discussing buyout group presentations to financing sources and ratings agencies, including management's explanation that poor shortterm performance had resulted from "conscious tradeoffs to reposition and transform the company" (JX 660 at 32)); id. at *17 (comparing analyst response to results which focused on quarterly earnings miss with Boston Consulting Group's internal analysis concluding that Dell's longterm earning power would not be adversely affected (JX 536)); id. at *19 (comparing International Data Corporation's response to quarterly results with buyout group's longterm projections to lenders and related assessment of company (JX 669; JX 678)); id. at *3435 (summarizing evidence of valuation gap, including JX 96; JX 109; JX 110; JX 137; JX 170; JX 226; JX 344; JX 530).
That said, I do not question the Delaware Supreme Court's authority to elevate the importance for a fair value determination of a trading price generated by a market with attributes associated with semistrong form efficiency. I also do not question the Delaware Supreme Court's authority to hold that a trial court should require evidence sufficient to make findings undermining market efficiency before considering and regarding as persuasive casespecific evidence of the views of knowledgeable insiders. See Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *17 (observing that I did not make any findings inconsistent with the premises of market efficiency, such as findings that "Dell lacked a vast and diffuse base of public stockholders, that information about the Company was sparse or restricted, that there was not an active trading market for Dell's shares, or that Dell had a controlling stockholder—or that the market for its stock lacked any of the hallmarks of an efficient market").

The DFC decision points to the same conclusion. There, the Court of Chancery found DFC's performance "appeared to be in a trough, with future performance depending on the outcome of regulatory decision-making that was largely out of the company's control." The trial court relied on record evidence that the acquirer "was aware of DFC's trough performance and uncertain outlook" and that "these attributes were at the core of [the acquirer's] investment thesis to obtain assets with potential upside at a favorable price." On appeal, the Delaware Supreme Court explained that "the market's assessment of the future cash flows necessarily takes regulatory risk into account as it does with all the other reasonable uncertain factors that affect a company's future." The senior tribunal found that "the record reveals that equity analysts, equity buyers, debt analysts, debt providers and others were in fact attuned to the regulatory risks facing DFC." The same reasoning applies here in terms of the ability of equity analysts and other market participants to assess the risk associated with Project Greyhound and Aruba's ability to meet management guidance.

In re Appraisal of DFC Glob. Corp. (DFC Trial), 2016 WL 3753123, at *22 (Del. Ch. July 8, 2016), rev'd sub nom. DFC Glob. Corp. v. Muirfield Value P'rs, L.P., 172 A.3d 346 (Del. 2017).

Id. (citing Barner Tr. 533-37 and JX 428 at 16).

Id. at 373.

The Delaware Supreme Court in DFC also questioned whether a trial court should have relied on evidence that the buyer thought it was getting a good deal to support the possibility of underpricing:

One would expect a buyer to think it made a wise decision with an upside, and, to be candid, it is in tension with the statute itself to argue that the subjective view of post-merger value of the acquirer can be used to value the respondent company in an appraisal, as the statute's exclusion of transaction-specific value seems to be directed at the concern a buyer who pays fair value should not have its economic upside for taking that risk expropriated in the appraisal process, a result that if it were the law, would discourage sales transactions valuable to selling stockholders. That a buyer views itself as having struck a good deal is far from reliable evidence that the resulting price from a competitive bidding process is an unreliable indicator of fair value. . . . [O]ne would think that the buyer who paid the highest price in a competitive process had the most confidence there was an upside and must think that post-purchase gains would justify its purchase; otherwise, no sale would ever occur in the world. That [the acquirer] expected to profit does not mean that the collective view of value that results from the deal price is not a reliable indicator of fair value; to hold otherwise, is to adopt a non-binary view of fair value in which only the upside view of what could happen in the future is taken into account.
This passage cautions against regarding HP's belief that it had seized upon an opportune time to purchase Aruba as sufficient to undercut the reliability of Aruba's market price.

Id. at 374 n.145. To the extent a buyer bases its assessment on synergistic gains or other aspects of value that would not exist but for the transaction, the Delaware Supreme Court's "candid" observation regarding tension with the statutory standard makes sense to me. To the extent that a buyer is assessing the target's standalone value in its pre-deal configuration, it is not clear to me why any tension would exist. I personally would regard the beliefs of knowledgeable market participants, including the buyer, as relevant evidence of fair value. See In re Appraisal of Dole Food Co., Inc., 114 A.3d 541 (Del. Ch. 2014) (ordering production of valuation materials prepared by appraisal petitioners when deciding whether to purchase or sell shares of the subject company's stock). The market price is, after all, merely an aggregation of the views of knowledgeable market participants. Id. at 559 ("The market price . . . represents an aggregation of the views that many lay people hold about the value of a stock."); see also DFC, 172 A.3d at 367 (discussing "the collective judgment of value embodied in a market price"). Nor would one need to exclude the possibility of downside risk when evaluating the buyer's valuation, to the extent that the buyer had not already taken that risk into account. A court could consider evidence showing that the buyer's assessment was overly optimistic. In the past, courts deciding appraisal cases have considered conceptually similar valuation indications. Chancellor Allen considered the fact that "knowledgeable officers and directors all sold their stock" at the transaction price. Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc., 1990 WL 161084, at *32 (Del. Ch. Oct. 19, 1990) (Allen, C.), aff'd in part and rev'd in part on other grounds, 634 A.2d 345 (Del. 1993). Chancellor Chandler considered third-party offers to purchase corporate assets, such as a wholly owned subsidiary whose operations were not affected by the merger giving rise to appraisal rights. See Ryan v. Tad's Enters., Inc., 709 A.2d 682, 702 (Del. Ch. 1996) (considering offers to purchase one of corporation's two remaining businesses four months after the merger, one year after the merger, and two years after the merger).
That said, I do not question the Delaware Supreme Court's authority to instruct the trial courts that when determining fair value, they should give less weight to the views of individual market participants, such as the buyer, and more weight to the collective views of many market participants, aggregated through trading, or the information generated by a sale process.

3. Bundling Aruba's Earnings Release With The Merger Announcement

So far, the petitioners' evidence of a market trough or other mispricing is conceptually similar to the types of evidence that the Delaware Supreme Court rejected in Dell and DFC. But the petitioners advanced another argument that falls into a slightly different category because it involved Aruba and HP making conscious decisions about when to release information. At the end of January 2015, HP offered to acquire Aruba for $23.25 per share. During the first week of February, while Aruba was considering its response, another analyst report criticized the Company, and the stock price fell again, closing around $16.07 the day after the report. Contrary to the market's perception, Aruba management knew internally that Aruba was having an excellent quarter and would beat its guidance. But, rather than correcting the market's perception, Aruba management proposed to time the announcement of the merger to coincide with the announcement of Aruba's February 2015 earnings. Companies often announce significant items as part of an earnings release, particularly if the earnings are bad and the news is good (or vice versa). In this case, Aruba management believed that an increase in the stock price would hurt their chances of getting the deal approved. Providing both pieces of information simultaneously would blur the market's reaction to Aruba's strong quarterly results and help get the deal approved.

JX 466 at 1-2 (internal Aruba email distributing report).

Id. at 1 (email from Aruba General Counsel suggesting the stock price "reflects the misconception that we missed. We actually beat guidance but no one knows that yet").

The idea of announcing the merger along with Aruba's strong quarterly results came from Aruba management, not HP. When Whitman and Neri first re-engaged with Orr at dinner on January 21, 2015, Orr suggested announcing the deal at an industry conference at the beginning of March. JX 423 (email from Orr relaying exchange to Aruba management). When Johansson contacted Orr at the end of January to notify him HP intended to bid imminently, Orr accelerated the timeline, proposing "getting a deal announced by [Aruba's] earnings on Feb 26." JX 454 (internal Barclays email summarizing Johansson's relay of the call). When Evercore later attempted to negotiate with HP's banker, Evercore again "emphasized that [Aruba would] like to announce [the] deal at or before the [Aruba] earnings announcement" because Aruba was "afraid stock runs like Ubiquiti's did which could make the deal more challenging from the [Aruba] perspective." JX 491 (email from Barclays to HP recounting exchange).

See, e.g., DFC Trial, 2016 WL 3753123, at *13 ("[D]iscouraging financial results [were] issued on April 2, 2014, the same day the transaction was announced."); In re Dollar Thrifty S'holder Litig., 14 A.3d 573, 591 (Del. Ch. Sept. 8, 2010) (Strine, V.C.) ("Dollar Thrifty's advisors were suspicious that Hertz wanted to use the deal to cover up what would be an otherwise disappointing earnings announcement, but eventually concluded that Frissora's eagerness was attributable to a normal desire to announce the deal in conjunction with an earnings release."); In re Trans World Airlines, Inc. S'holders Litig., 1988 WL 111271, at *4 (Del. Ch. Oct. 21, 1988) ("The proposal now under consideration was announced . . . the same day on which the Company announced very favorable financial results for the first quarter of 1988."), abrogated on other grounds by Kahn v. Lynch Commc'n Sys., Inc., 638 A.2d 1110 (Del. 1994); see also Boutros Dep. 203 ("[I]t's very customary, very, very customary, if you're pursuing an M&A transaction and it's close to being done, . . . and you have an earnings release, to make the two concurrent, because these are two material events that will impact the stock price, and the last thing you want to do is release material information piecemeal to your shareholders."); cf. In re Smurfit-Stone Container Corp. S'holder Litig., 2011 WL 2028076, at *8 (Del. Ch. May 20, 2011) ("[The bidder] threatened to suspend the merger discussions if the proposed transaction could not be finalized before the end of the weekend and the release of both companies' earnings announcements the following week.").

HP agreed to this course of action, which favored HP's interests. HP also may have leaked news of the deal to further mask the significance of Aruba's strong earnings. On February 25, 2015, one day before Aruba was scheduled to announce its earnings, Bloomberg News ran a story on the merger. JX 866 (article). Qatalyst speculated internally that HP had leaked the news so that Aruba's "results and subsequent stock price reaction won't be easy to measure." JX 510. Aruba's stock price jumped from $18.37 to $22.24. Proxy at 53.

In Dell, the Delaware Supreme Court implied that a petitioner might be able to call into question the integrity of the market price if they proved that management had withheld information from the market or misled investors. As one of its several reasons for holding that I abused my discretion, the high court noted that I "expressly found no evidence that information failed to flow freely or that management purposefully tempered investors' expectations for the Company so that it could eventually take over the Company at a fire-sale price." My prediction of the law before the Delaware Supreme Court's decision in Dell would have been that scienter did not matter for an appraisal case where the sole litigable question is valuation rather than culpability. But this passage indicates that whether management causes an informational distortion is pertinent not only for a breach of fiduciary duty claim or fraud action, but for an appraisal proceeding as well.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *18

In this case, the petitioners contend that Aruba and HP manipulated the timing of announcing Aruba's strong quarterly results and the merger to interfere with investors' ability to perceive Aruba's standalone value. The petitioners do not contend that management never provided the quarterly results or falsified the quarterly results, only that they bundled them together with the announcement of the merger.

As framed by the Delaware Supreme Court in Dell and DFC, the semi-strong form of the efficient capital markets hypothesis does not contemplate that directional error will arise from the order in which information is released or from bundling information together. Releasing information simultaneously or in close proximity might make it difficult for an expert to disentangle the price reaction for purposes of an event study, but the market still would have the information and would respond. As the high court stated in Dell, when a market is efficient, "a mass of investors quickly digests all publicly available information about a company and, in trading the company's stock, recalibrates its price to reflect the market's adjusted, consensus valuation of the company." And as the high court observed in DFC, "in an efficient market, you can trust prices, for they impound all available information about the value of each security." Aruba's stock traded briefly above the deal price, indicating the market took into account both the announcement of the deal and Aruba's strong results. Viewed within the framework established by DFC and Dell, the record does not provide a persuasive reason to question the reliability of Aruba's trading price based on the decision by Aruba management to bundle together two pieces of information.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *17.

DFC, 172 A.3d at 370 (citation and internal quotation marks omitted).

But cf. Jonathan R. Macey & Geoffrey P. Miller, Good Finance, Bad Economics: An Analysis of the Fraud-on-the-Market Theory, 42 Stan. L. Rev. 1059, 1084-85 (1990) (explaining that efficient markets may process different types of information at different rates and with different effects). Perhaps in an appropriate case an expert could opine that the order in which information was released or the fact that information was bundled together had some meaningful effect. No one made that argument or offered that opinion here. Absent a case-specific expert opinion supported by credible evidence and the weight of social-science research, I do not believe a trial judge has the flexibility to disregard the Delaware Supreme Court's framing of the implications of the efficient capital markets hypothesis.

4. The Conclusion Regarding The Market Price Evidence

Aruba's thirty-day average unaffected market price was $17.13. Viewed within the framework established by DFC and Dell, Aruba's market price provides reliable evidence of the going concern value of the firm.

JX 659.

B. The Deal Price

The Delaware Supreme Court's recent decisions in DFC and Dell hold that when a widely held, publicly traded company has been sold in an arm's-length transaction, the deal price has "heavy, if not overriding, probative value." Applying that standard in this case, the merger price carries heavy weight, although the inclusion of elements of value arising from the merger requires adjustments to generate an indication of fair value.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *22.

1. The Role Of The Deal Price

On three occasions, the Delaware Supreme Court has declined to establish a presumption regarding the relationship between the deal price and fair value. In Golden Telecom, the high court explained that "Section 262(h) neither dictates nor even contemplates that the Court of Chancery should consider the transactional market price of the underlying company. Rather, in determining 'fair value,' the statute instructs that the court 'shall take into account all relevant factors.'" The court reasoned that "[r]equiring the Court of Chancery to defer—conclusively or presumptively—to the merger price, even in the face of a pristine, unchallenged transactional process, would contravene the unambiguous language of the statute and the reasoned holdings of our precedent."

Golden Telecom, Inc. v. Glob. GT LP, 11 A.3d 214, 217-18 (Del. 2010) (quoting 8 Del. C. § 262(h)).

Id. at 218.

In DFC, the Delaware Supreme Court again rejected a request to establish a presumption that the deal price reflects fair value, seeing "no license in the statue for creating a presumption" and expressing doubt about "our ability to craft, on a general basis, the precise pre-conditions that would be necessary to invoke a presumption of that kind." At the same time, the Delaware Supreme Court cautioned that its

refusal to craft a statutory presumption in favor the deal price when certain conditions pertain does not in any way signal our ignorance to the economic reality that the sale value resulting from a robust market check will often be the most reliable evidence of fair value, and that second-guessing the value arrived upon by the collective views of many sophisticated parties with a real stake in the matter is hazardous.
The Delaware Supreme Court also cautioned that "we have little quibble with the economic argument that the price of a merger that results from a robust market check, against the back drop of a rich information base and a welcoming environment for potential buyers, is probative of the company's fair value."

Id.

Id.

The DFC court reversed a decision by this court to give only one-third weight to the deal price. The high court noted that the trial court had made the following post-trial findings of fact:

i) the transaction resulted from a robust market search that lasted approximately two years in which financial and strategic buyers had an open opportunity to buy without inhibition of deal protections;

ii) the company was purchased by a third party in an arm's length sale; and

iii) there was no hint of self-interest that compromised the market check.
The high court further observed that
[a]lthough there is no presumption in favor of the deal price, under the conditions found by the Court of Chancery, economic principles suggest that the best evidence of fair value was the deal price, as it resulted from an open process, informed by robust public information, and easy access to deeper,
non-public information, in which many parties with an incentive to make a profit had a chance to bid.
The Delaware Supreme Court determined that the Court of Chancery's "decision to give one-third weight to each metric was unexplained and in tension with the Court of Chancery's own findings about the robustness of the market check." The senior tribunal therefore reversed and remanded the case so the trial court could "reassess [its] conclusion as to fair value in light of our decision."

Id. at 349 (formatting added).

Id.

Id. at 388.

Id. at 388-89.

Most recently, in Dell, the Delaware Supreme Court reiterated that "there is no requirement that the court assign some mathematical weight to the deal price." On the facts presented, however, the high court held that I "erred in not assigning any mathematical weight to the deal price" under circumstances suggesting that "the deal price deserved heavy, if not dispositive weight." Those circumstances included (i) stock market attributes associated with efficient trading and (ii) a sale process that involved "fair play, low barriers to entry, outreach to all logical buyers, and the chance for any topping bidder to have the support of Mr. Dell's own votes."

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *16.

Id.; accord id. at *22 ("Overall, the weight of evidence shows that Dell's deal price has heavy, if not overriding, probative value.").

Id. at *17.

Id. at *26.

The decisions in DFC and Dell identify factors that make the deal price so probative that a trial court abuses its discretion by failing to give it enough weight, but they provide less guidance for determining when a process is sufficiently bad to warrant discounting the deal price. One passage in the DFC decision suggests an answer to the latter inquiry by stating that

the purpose of an appraisal is not to make sure that the petitioners get the highest conceivable value that might have been procured had every domino fallen out of the company's way; rather, it is to make sure that they receive fair compensation for their shares in the sense that it reflects what they deserve to receive based on what would fairly be given to them in an arm's-length transaction.
This test focuses on whether the deal in question was an arm's-length transaction, and it appears to rule out inquiry into whether a different transaction process might have achieved a superior result. A passage from Dell points in a similar direction, where the high court stated: "The issue in an appraisal is not whether a negotiator has extracted the highest possible bid. Rather, the key inquiry is whether the dissenters got fair value and were not exploited." As with the passage from DFC, the passage from Dell appears to discount whether a different approach might have done better. The Dell test turns on exploitation.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *24. The reference to "dissenters" in this sentence strikes me as odd because the dissenters have opted not to receive the merger consideration. By seeking appraisal, they avoided the possibility of being "exploited" by the deal. The larger point seems to be for the trial judge to assess whether the deal price is somehow exploitive such that it would exploit the dissenters for the court to use it as the basis for awarding fair value.

2. The Deal Price In This Case

In this case, the HP-Aruba transaction was a third-party, arm's-length merger. HP was not a controller engaged in squeezing out the minority. Nor was the transaction a management buyout where insiders' informational advantages might have raised concerns. The transaction did not involve particular stockholders, such as members of management or a large blockholder, rolling over their shares or otherwise receiving differential treatment. Nothing about the deal structure could be considered exploitive.

The ultimate decision makers for Aruba—the Board and the stockholders—did not labor under any conflicts of interest. The Board was disinterested and independent. Of its eight members, six were experienced, outside directors. Aruba's stockholder base was widely dispersed. No one identified any stockholders with a dominant position or divergent interests.

Aruba negotiated with HP over the price. On January 31, 2015, HP sent Aruba a written indication of interest for a cash transaction at $23.25 per share, for an aggregate valuation of $2.563 billion. Aruba countered at $29 per share. While HP considered Aruba's counter, it learned that Aruba in fact had fewer shares outstanding than HP had believed. HP had based the $23.25 per share price on Aruba's old share count. When HP recalculated its offer to reflect the correct share count, the same aggregate consideration of $2.563 billion resulted in a price per share of $23.89. Based on that calculation, HP raised its bid to $24.67 per share, or just over 3% on an as-adjusted basis. Aruba asked for $25.00 per share, but HP held firm.

JX 452 at 3 ("Indicative Non-Binding Proposal").

JX 234 (minutes); accord Warmenhoven Tr. 261 (testifying the Aruba Board came to the figure because "[w]e wanted to reaffirm that we thought there was great value there, meaning they should bid higher, but we felt like if we put a 3 in the first digit and started at 30, that they might conclude that's too big a gap to close and stop discussion").

JX 491 (email from Barclays to HP relaying Evercore's counter); accord JX 488 at 4 (internal Evercore emails confirming change in shares outstanding and suggesting repurchases caused the change).

JX 798 at 2 (Barclays slide entitled "Impact of New Share Count and B/S Data on Offer Price").

Proxy at 52.

Id.

There is evidence that the price credited Aruba with a portion of the substantial synergies that the transaction would generate from combining Aruba's strength in wireless networking with HP's strength in wired systems. HP's final internal analysis, reflecting independent research and validation by McKinsey, anticipated total synergies of $1.41 billion, consisting of revenue synergies of $1.175 billion and cost synergies of $235 million.

See Marcus Tr. 151; Warmenhoven Tr. 264 (describing HP and Aruba as a "perfect match" because "HP had all the switches and routers" but "no WiFi to speak of"); id. at 276-77 (calling the synergies "[v]ery substantial" and noting the acquisition "was part of not just acquiring share in networking, but a bigger, broader enterprise strategy"); Orr Tr. 434-35 (discussing the benefits the transaction offered to both Aruba and HP); Galvin Tr. 578 ("[T]he win-win is HP provided us the muscle that we never had to really stand up to Cisco in the high end of the corporate stack, in the big deals. And particularly when you start to talk about a wired-wireless convergence, they provided a tremendous amount of muscle for us to do that."); DePuy Tr. 682 ("[W]hen you put those two together, they could attack customers in a way they could neither do individually."); Dages Tr. 753-54, 783; see also JX 805 at 2 (late-stage internal HP approval deck noting the acquisition "will provide complementary go to market and wireless capabilities and uniquely position[] HP as the market moves towards a unified wired/wireless solution"); id. at 7-8 (estimating approximately $1.4 billion in synergies); id. at 26 (slide titled "[Aruba] Fills Key Product Gaps Across HPN's WLAN Product Portfolio").

JX 805; see also JX 350 (similar deck for earlier approval); JX 356 (same); JX 383 (McKinsey synergy analysis). The petitioners argued that the court cannot rely on HP's analyses because they are hearsay. The petitioners raised their objections in the Pre-Trial Order and again at trial. See PTO ¶¶ 585-86 & Ex. A (objecting to JX 350 and JX 805); Warmenhoven Tr. 273-74 (objecting to JX 350 as "hearsay posed" to Warmenhoven because "[h]e's never seen the document").
Hearsay "is a statement, other than one made by the declarant while testifying at the trial or hearing, offered in evidence to prove the truth of the matter asserted." D.R.E. 801(c). "Hearsay is not admissible except as provided by law or by [the Delaware Uniform Rules of Evidence]." D.R.E. 802. Rule of Evidence 803(6) recognizes an exception for documents

made at or near the time by, or from information transmitted by, a person with knowledge, if kept in the course of a regularly conducted business activity, and if it was the regular practice of that business activity to make the [document], all as shown by the testimony of the custodian or other qualified witness . . . unless the source of information or the method or circumstances of preparation indicate lack of trustworthiness.
D.R.E. 803(6). "The business records exception to the hearsay rule permits the admission of hearsay documents that are likely to be trustworthy because a business regularly maintains and relies on them." Brown v. Liberty Mut. Ins. Co., 774 A.2d 232, 239 (Del. 2001). "The principal precondition to admission of documents as a business record . . . is that the records have sufficient indicia of trustworthiness to be considered reliable." Id. (quoting Saks Int'l, Inc. v. M/V Exp. Champion, 817 F.2d 1011, 1013 (2d Cir. 1987)).

Johansson testified extensively by deposition about HP's thorough, routine approval process for reviewing and approving transactions of this nature. See PTO ¶ 575 (stipulating Johansson would testify "by deposition"). He testified that the process regularly includes an "Approval to Negotiate," such as the one contained in JX 350, and an "Approval to Sign," such as the one contained in JX 805. See Johansson Dep. 22-25. Although Johansson's testimony did not explicitly address those two exhibits, his testimony satisfies me that HP prepared and maintained them in the ordinary course of its business. They therefore have the indicia of trustworthiness contemplated by Rule of Evidence 803(6). The petitioners' selective introduction of similar, and in some cases nearly identical, documents bolsters this conclusion. See, e.g., JX 356 (draft Approval to Negotiate deck); JX 398 at 6 (internal HP "discussion materials" deck); JX 780 (later-dated internal HP "discussion materials" deck).

HP and Aruba agreed to terms for the merger agreement that the petitioners have not meaningfully challenged. The merger agreement contained a no-shop clause that prevented Aruba from communicating with third parties about an acquisition proposal unless both the Aruba Board's fiduciary duties required it and the acquisition proposal was reasonably likely to lead to a superior proposal. The merger agreement granted HP an unlimited match right, with five days to match the first superior proposal and two days to match any subsequent increase, and during the match period Aruba had to negotiate exclusively and in good faith with HP. The merger agreement provided that if the Aruba Board complied with the no-solicitation provision, including the match right, then the Aruba Board could terminate the merger agreement to accept a superior proposal after first paying HP a termination fee of $90 million, or 3% of equity value. This combination of defensive provisions would not have supported a claim for breach of fiduciary duty.

See JX 907 § 5.2(b)(ii).

Id. at § 5.2(b)(ii)(A), (B).

Id. at § 5.2(b)(ii)(B)(3).

Id. at § 7.2(b)(iv).

See, e.g., Dent v. Ramtron Int'l Corp., 2014 WL 2931180, at *8-10 (Del. Ch. June 30, 2014) (rejecting fiduciary challenge to "(1) a no-solicitation provision; (2) a standstill provision; (3) a change in recommendation provision; (4) information rights for [the acquirer]; and (5) a $5 million termination fee" where the termination fee represented 4.5% of equity value and the change of recommendation provision included an unlimited match right); In re Novell, Inc. S'holder Litig., 2013 WL 322560, at *10 (Del. Ch. Jan. 3, 2013) (describing "the no solicitation provision, the matching rights provision, and the termination fee" as "customary and well within the range permitted under Delaware law" and observing that "[t]he mere inclusion of such routine terms does not amount to a breach of fiduciary duty"); In re Answers Corp. S'holders Litig., 2011 WL 1366780, at *4 & n.47 (Del. Ch. Apr. 11, 2011) (describing "a termination fee plus expense reimbursement of 4.4% of the Proposed Transaction's equity value, a no solicitation clause, a 'no-talk' provision limiting the Board's ability to discuss an alternative transaction with an unsolicited bidder, a matching rights provision, and a force-the-vote requirement" as "standard merger terms" that "do not alone constitute breaches of fiduciary duty" (citation omitted)); In re Atheros Commc'ns, Inc. S'holder Litig., 2011 WL 864928, at *7 n.61 (Del. Ch. Mar. 4, 2011) (characterizing a no-solicitation provision, a matching right, and a termination fee as "standard merger terms" that "do not alone constitute breaches of fiduciary duty" (citation omitted)); In re 3Com S'holders Litig., 2009 WL 5173804, at *7 (Del. Ch. Dec. 18, 2009) (describing "the no solicitation provision, the matching rights provision, and the termination fee" as "standard merger terms" that "do not alone constitute breaches of fiduciary duty").

Considering these factors as a whole, the HP-Aruba merger looks like a run-of-the-mill, third-party deal. Nothing about it appears exploitive. Particularly given the inclusion of synergies, there is good reason to think that the deal price exceeded fair value and, if anything, should establish a ceiling for fair value.

See DFC, 172 A.3d at 371 ("[I]t is widely assumed that the sale price in many M&A deals includes a portion of the buyer's expected synergy gains, which is part of the premium the winning buyer must pay to prevail and obtain control."); Merion Capital L.P. v. Lender Processing Servs., Inc., 2016 WL 7324170, at *11, *26 (Del. Ch. Dec. 16, 2016) (noting that evidence supported the view that the merger consideration "included a portion of the value that [the acquirers] expected to generate from synergies" and that "[t]he existence of combinatorial synergies provides an additional reason to think that" the merger consideration "exceeded the fair value of the Company"); see also Olson v. EV3, Inc., 2011 WL 704409, at *10 (Del. Ch. Feb. 21, 2011) ("In an arm's-length, synergistic transaction, the deal price generally will exceed fair value because target fiduciaries bargain for a premium that includes . . . a share of the anticipated synergies . . . ."); Union Ill. 1995 Inv. Ltd. P'ship v. Union Fin. Gp., Ltd., 847 A.2d 340, 356 (Del. Ch. 2003) (Strine, V.C.) ("[A]cquirers typically share a portion of synergies with sellers in sales transactions and that portion is value that would be left wholly in the hands of the selling company's stockholders, as a price that the buyer was willing to pay to capture the selling company and the rest of the synergies.").

a. The Absence Of Competition

In an effort to undermine the probative value of the deal price, the petitioners argue that HP did not face a meaningful threat of competition. They note that the recent decisions in Dell and DFC cited with approval the open nature of the deal processes in those cases.

See Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *20-22 (describing company's efforts to generate competition for the buy-out group); DFC, 172 A.3d at 349 (relying on the Court of Chancery's finding that "the transaction resulted from a robust market search that lasted approximately two years in which financial and strategic buyers had an open opportunity to buy without inhibition of deal protections"). Before Dell and DFC, a series of Court of Chancery decisions had stressed the importance of competition during the sale process. See In re PetSmart, Inc., 2017 WL 2303599, at *40 n.439 (Del. Ch. May 26, 2017) (giving exclusive weight to merger price where "negotiated at arm's-length, in real time, after a well-run pre-signing auction that takes place in the midst of a fully functioning market"); Merion Capital LP v. BMC Software, Inc., 2015 WL 6164771, at *14-15 (Del. Ch. Oct. 21, 2015) (giving exclusive weight to merger price where the company conducted "a robust, arm's-length sales process" that involved "two auctions over a period of several months," and "was able to and did engage multiple potential buyers during these periods," and where the lone remaining bidder "raised its bid multiple times because it believed the auction was still competitive"); LongPath Capital, LLC v. Ramtron Int'l Corp., 2015 WL 4540443, at *9 (Del. Ch. June 30, 2015) (relying on "thorough" sale process initiated in response to "a well-publicized hostile bid and a target actively seeking a white knight"); In re Appraisal of Ancestry.com, Inc., 2015 WL 399726, at *1 (Del. Ch. Jan. 20, 2015) (giving exclusive weight to the deal price where the transaction resulted from an "auction process, which process itself involved a market canvas and uncovered a motivated buyer"); Merlin P'rs LP v. AutoInfo, Inc., 2015 WL 2069417, at *12 (Del. Ch. Jan. 9, 2015) (giving exclusive weight to merger price that "was negotiated at arm's length, without compulsion, and with adequate information" and it was "the result of competition among many potential acquirers"); Huff Fund Inv. P'ship v. CKx, Inc., 2013 WL 5878807, at *14 (Del. Ch. Nov. 1, 2013) (evaluating sale process and concluding that "the bidders were in fact engaged in a process resembling the English ascending-bid auction" involving direct competition between bidders); Union Ill., 847 A.2d at 359 (using merger price as "best indicator of value" where the merger "resulted from a competitive and fair auction" in which "several buyers with a profit motive" were able to evaluate the company and "make bids with actual money behind them").

The Dell and DFC decisions did not hold that a deal price would be rendered unreliable in the absence of competition. Instead, the high court indicated that, for an appraisal petitioner to call into question a deal process based on lack of competition, the petitioner should be able to point to a likely bidder and make a persuasive showing that increased competition would have led to a better result. The Dell decision stressed that "[f]air value entails at minimum a price some buyer is willing to pay—not a price at which no class of buyers in the market would pay." "[I]f a company is one that no strategic buyer is interested in buying, it does not suggest a higher value, but a lower one."

See Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *20 ("Nothing in the record suggests that increased competition would have produced a better result."); id. at *21 ("The Court of Chancery stressed its view that the lack of competition from a strategic buyer lowered the relevance of the deal price. But its assessment that more bidders—both strategic and financial—should have been involved assumes there was some party interested in proceeding. Nothing in the record indicates that was the case."); see also id. at *23 ("[A]side from the theoretical, the Court of Chancery did not point to any bidder who actually shied away from exploring an acquisition out of fear of the winner's curse phenomenon."); id. at *25 ("[T]he court did not identify any possible bidders that were actually deterred because of Mr. Dell's status.").

Id.

Id.; see also DFC, 172 A.3d at 375 n.154 ("[T]he absence of synergistic buyers for a company is itself relevant to its value.").

Other aspects of the Dell and DFC decisions similarly discounted the importance of competition. The DFC decision stressed that the purpose of an appraisal "is not to make sure that the petitioners get the highest conceivable value," and the Dell decision cautioned that "[t]he issue . . . is not whether a negotiator has extracted the highest possible bid." Competition might help a seller extract a higher price, but that is not the focus of the inquiry under Dell and DFC.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *24.

The role of competition also must be evaluated in light of the Delaware Supreme Court's endorsement of the efficient capital markets hypothesis. At the trial level, Chancellor Bouchard found in DFC and I found in Dell that the market prices of the acquired firms were depressed and had not been representative of fair value. From that factual starting point, we examined the sale processes for evidence of competition or a meaningful threat of competition that would be sufficient to overcome the market mispricing and generate fair value. On appeal in DFC and Dell, the Delaware Supreme Court relied on the efficient capital markets hypothesis to hold that the factual findings about market troughs constituted abuses of discretion. From that different factual starting point, there is less need for competition among bidders to drive a meaningful sale process, and less need for a court to delve into the details. With a reliable market price as the base line, an arm's-length deal at a premium is non-exploitive. By definition, it provides stockholders with "fair compensation for their shares," defined as "what they deserve to receive based on what would fairly be given to them in an arm's-length transaction."

In this case, the petitioners proved that HP knew it did not face a meaningful threat of competition. In October 2014, during its first pass at Aruba, HP's executives established a "pretty open dialogue" with Orr, and he informed HP that Aruba was "not running a sales process." Orr did not make any effort to create the impression of competition by "posturing about trying to pin [HP] against someone else." HP consequently did not feel any pressure to bid. After three full months of discussions and due diligence, HP still had not put a number on the table.

See JX 348 (email from Neri to Whitman).

Johansson Dep. 112.

Id.

Aruba has pointed out that, at the end of November 2014, Orr decided that the discussion had dragged on long enough, and he terminated them with the Aruba Board's backing. Under different circumstances, this move might have given Aruba some bargaining leverage by signaling that Aruba was prepared to pursue its standalone plan. But in this case, Orr undercut that implication when he had dinner with Whitman and Neri on January 21, 2015. After Whitman told Orr that HP still wanted to acquire Aruba, Orr responded enthusiastically and proposed to announce the deal at an industry conference during the first week of March. Days later, when an HP executive called Orr to say that HP would be sending over its proposal, Orr suggested getting a deal announced by the end of February.

See Proxy at 48-49; see also JX 328 ("We have been in dialogue with [HP] since August 27, and have not received a proposal in all this time. . . . We cannot continue to wait for them."); JX 367 (email from Aruba to Qatalyst advising it had "decided to terminate discussions with [HP] at this time" and that it would "let [Qatalyst] know if discussions resume"); JX 372 at 1-2 (email from Aruba General Counsel relaying conversation with Johansson during which she explained that "[w]e feel it's time to suspend discussions" because "it has reached a point where we need to focus on running our business and not be distracted by discussions that did not seem to be progressing").

See Lender Processing, 2016 WL 7324170, at *19 ("The Board's track record of saying 'no' gave [the acquirers] a credible reason to believe that the Board would not sell below its internal reserve price.").

PTO ¶ 155.

JX 423 (email from Orr relaying exchange to Aruba management).

JX 454 (internal Barclays email summarizing executive's relay of the call).

HP's bidding tactics suggest that HP knew it did not face competition. Before the dinner with Orr, HP planned to open with $24.00 per share and negotiate up to $25.00. After Orr's response, HP lowered its opening bid to $23.25. When Aruba countered at $29, Barclays told Evercore that any price increase would be on the scale of "quarters, not dollars." Based on a new share count that Evercore provided, HP recalculated its opening bid as equating to $23.89 per share. This was still below the planned opening bid of $24.00 per share that HP contemplated before Whitman and Neri had dinner with Orr. With the lower share count, the same enterprise value generated a price of $24.67 per share. HP told Aruba that its best and final bid was $24.67, which HP internally called "the new $24.00" because the price merely adjusted for the change in Aruba's public share count. HP increased its bid to $24.67 and refused to budge. The deal ended up at the number HP had planned to use for its opening bid.

JX 398 at 1-2 (cover email for deck seeking board approval); JX 805 at 12 (internal HP deck).

JX 452 at 3 ("Indicative Non-Binding Proposal").

Proxy at 51.

JX 798 at 2 (Barclays slide entitled "Impact of New Share Count and B/S Data on Offer Price").

Id.

JX 497 (internal HP email from Johansson); accord JX 805 at 12 (timeline showing "02/08 - HP offer $24.00 and present as best and final. [Aruba] provide new shares outstanding and cash information supporting paying $24.67 at the same enterprise value.").

JX 235 at 1-2 (minutes); Proxy at 52.

So far, so good for the petitioners. But although they proved that HP knew it did not face a meaningful threat of competition, they failed to identify any other likely bidder who would have paid more for Aruba. The Dell decision teaches that "[f]air value entails at minimum a price some buyer is willing to pay." Elaborating, the court emphasized that, if no one else is interested in buying, "it does not suggest a higher value, but a lower one." In this case, Aruba (through Qatalyst) contacted six potential strategic partners; none were interested. Nor did anyone come forward after the deal announcement. Under Dell and DFC, the petitioners failed to undermine the deal price by showing a lack of competition. Instead, the lack of competition supports the reliability of the deal price.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *21.

Id.; see also DFC, 172 A.3d at 375 n.154 ("[T]he absence of synergistic buyers for a company is itself relevant to its value.").

See Warmenhoven Tr. 260 ("[I]t was definitive noninterest."); id. 329-30 (agreeing potential bidders provided "feedback" that they "had no strategic interest in acquiring Aruba" and that it "[h]ad nothing to do with the price").

Under Dell and DFC, the test instead is whether the Aruba-HP transaction was exploitive. "[T]he purpose of an appraisal is not to make sure that the petitioners get the highest conceivable value . . . ." This decision already has found that Aruba's stock price exhibited attributes associated with the premises of the efficient capital markets hypothesis. The merger consideration of $24.67 per share provided Aruba's stockholders with a significant premium over a reliable market price. As a result, the Aruba-HP transaction provided stockholders with "fair compensation for their shares," defined as "what they deserve to receive based on what would fairly be given to them in an arm's-length transaction."

Id. at 371.

b. The Negotiators' Incentives

The petitioners next contend that the deal price in this case is unreliable because Aruba's negotiators were compromised. The petitioners argue that Aruba's bankers catered to HP, and that Orr faced divergent interests of his own. Citing DFC and various trial court rulings, they argue that the deal price should be discounted because Aruba lacked representatives who engaged in vigorous, arm's-length bargaining on its behalf.

See, e.g., DFC, 172 A.3d at 349 (relying on the Court of Chancery's findings that "the company was purchased by a third party in an arm's length sale" and that "there was no hint of self-interest" in the transaction); PetSmart, 2017 WL 2303599, at *40 n.439 (acknowledging the persuasiveness of a merger price that was "negotiated at arm's-length"); BMC, 2015 WL 6164771, at *14 (giving exclusive weight to merger price where "[t]he record here demonstrates that the Company conducted a robust, arm's-length sales process"); AutoInfo, 2015 WL 2069417, at *12 (relying on the merger price where "[t]he Merger was negotiated at arm's length, without compulsion, and with adequate information"); CKx, 2013 WL 5878807, at *13 (giving exclusive weight to merger price where "the process by which CKx was marketed to potential buyers was thorough, effective, and free from any specter of self-interest or disloyalty"); Highfields Capital, Ltd. v. AXA Fin., Inc., 939 A.2d 34, 42 (Del. Ch. 2007) (stating that a reviewing court should give "substantial evidentiary weight" to the deal price when "the transaction giving rise to the appraisal resulted from an arm's-length process between two independent parties").

As with the element of competition, the petitioners regard the negotiators' incentives as a thread which, if pulled, could unravel the sweater. But like competition, the concept of negotiation cannot be excised from the broader framework that the DFC and Dell decisions established. The Dell opinion cautioned explicitly that "[t]he issue . . . is not whether a negotiator has extracted the highest possible bid." If this were a case where the market price was depressed or unreliable, then perhaps a detailed inquiry into issues like competition or negotiation might become important in assessing whether the deal process achieved fair value. In a scenario where the underlying market price is reliable, competition and negotiation become secondary. Under those circumstances, an arm's- length deal at a premium over the market price is non-exploitive. By definition, it gives stockholders "what would fairly be given to them in an arm's-length transaction."

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *24.

In this case, the petitioners proved that the Aruba's bankers catered to HP. Once Whitman refused to work opposite Qatalyst, Quattrone and Boutros perceived HP's stance as an existential threat to their technology-centered franchise. They wanted and needed to get back on HP's good side. Their primary goal from that point on was to rehabilitate their relationship with HP.

JX 412 at 1 ("Meg [Whitman] spoke with conviction and emotion over dinner that they [Qatalyst] were guilty." (referring to alleged fraud involving sale of Autonomy to HP)); JX 420 (Warmenhoven reporting that Whitman said "Qatalyst, Frank [Quattrone] & George [Boutros] are not welcome in the negotiations. The issue is bigger than Autonomy and goes back to EBay & Yahoo."); JX 426 (email from Orr to Aruba management updating them on Qatalyst situation and reporting that, when Boutros learned of HP's position, he was "so emotional, defensive AND offensive (to Meg [Whitman]) that he hardly let me talk"); accord Warmenhoven Tr. 252-53 (testifying that Whitman told him, "I don't care who you get, but it can't be Qatalyst" and that "I'm not going to take into my boardroom a deal proposed by Qatalyst"). Aruba has argued that, although Whitman refused to work with Qatalyst, she did not pick Aruba's banker. To my mind, these are questions of degree, with vetoing a banker to reduce the other side's choice set operating as a less extreme version of picking the other side's banker. In this case, however, vetoing effectively meant picking. Warmenhoven testified that, when considering bankers, Francis and Qatalyst were the only names who came up and that "there was no third name mentioned." Warmenhoven Tr. 238.

JX 437 at 1 (Warmenhoven explaining that, in Qatalyst's view, "[t]he issue is not Aruba. It is about the [Qatalyst] brand . . . . If word spreads that they were tossed from this deal because HP will not engage with them on any M&A transaction, that creates a big issue for them. . . . Frank wants to save his firm . . . . The relationship, or lack thereof, between [Qatalyst] and HP / Meg [Whitman] is now their focus."); see also JX 521 (Quattrone expressing concern that "Evercore will for sure be beating its chest about its role in this deal and could very well be telling the world that HP wouldn't do the deal if we were the advisor").

See JX 430 (Quattrone asking Warmenhoven to intervene with Whitman on his behalf); JX 434 at 1 (Quattrone asking Whitman for "the opportunity to speak or meet with you at your earliest convenience to understand from you directly what your concerns are and give me the opportunity to address them" and promising that "while our loyalties are always to our client on any assignment, I am confident we can address your concerns, play a constructive role and engage with your team in a professional manner"); JX 440 at 1 (email from Orr to Aruba management asking "how much time we allow" before saying "sorry, [Qatalyst]. We need to protect our transaction. [W]e cannot worry about your brand!"). At Quattrone's behest, Warmenhoven sent at least three emails to Whitman in a forty-eight-hour period in which he vouched for Qatalyst and asked Whitman to meet with Quattrone. See JX 430 (asking Whitman to meet personally with Quattrone); JX 436 (vouching for Quattrone and expressing confidence that "if you two could 'clear the air' [then] Frank and [Qatalyst] could be constructive participants in getting this deal done"); id. (following-up with Whitman and asking whether her objection was to Qatalyst or only to Boutros).

Evercore also wanted to get on HP's good side. The firm was a new entrant in the Silicon Valley market and had recently hired Francis as "their first tech sector person." Evercore understood the value of completing a highly visible deal as their first Silicon Valley transaction, and they saw the sale process as an extended audition for HP's business. During meetings between Aruba and HP, Evercore positioned itself as the banker to the deal. After one session, Francis reported to his colleagues that "it was fun to be the only banker in the room and help both sides think through some issues." He even bragged about having done "a 'masterful' job of taking [M]eg [Whitman] through the issues as if we were her advisor." Even accepting that investment bankers are always on the lookout for new clients, Evercore's eagerness in this case went far enough to undermine its role as Aruba's advisor.

JX 426 at 2 (internal Aruba email); see also JX 5 (executed engagement letter with Evercore showing fee of ¼%); JX 413 (Warmenhoven observing that "Evercore is new in the tech sector, so they may be willing to do a deal at ¼% just to get a deal done that they can brag about publicly"); Warmenhoven Tr. 241 (explaining that, when HP first approached Aruba in August 2014, he considered contacting Francis, but passed because he had no prior experience with Evercore and "didn't know the team").

See, e.g., JX 427 ("Truly amazing! This is a franchise transaction! Well done!"); id. ("This is franchise defining. Well done, and it shows the power of loyalty, which you have always eschewed! [sic]"); JX 428 ("Just remarkable, Stu [Francis.] What a coup! Would be, as you say, a dynamic advance for Evercore in The Valley."); JX 439 (congratulatory emails from two additional senior bankers).

JX 505 (Evercore bankers noting that that "[Whitman] is going to be very active" and that HP "[w]ould be a great new relationship.").

Id.

Id.

Warmenhoven testified that the bankers' relationships with HP did not negatively affect the negotiations and that having two bankers meant Aruba had "two star players on the same team." Orr testified similarly. Notwithstanding this testimony, I credit that the bankers' interests made them less effective negotiators than they might have been

Warmenhoven Tr. 255.

Orr Tr. 452.

The petitioners likewise proved that Orr had divergent interests, although his motivations were subtler and less openly mercenary. The sale to HP helped Orr achieve a combination of personal and professional goals that included hastening his return to a personally fulfilling retirement. That said, he was not about to leave Aruba under circumstances that would hurt the Company or its employees. From his standpoint, selling Aruba to HP was the perfect solution.

See Warmenhoven Tr. 228-31; id. at 273 (Orr's "going to be 66 in March. He's told me many times that he did not want to be in a regular employment situation when he turned 65"); id. at 289 ("[H]e was going to leave before his 65th birthday."); Orr Tr. 371-73 (describing activities during retirement, including spending time with his children, learning to cook, traveling to Japan and taking Japanese classes, working with The Philanthropy Workshop, and pursing other philanthropic endeavors including founding a non-profit business that provides low-power, solar-panel-driven phones); id. at 377 ("So every year I say, you know, it's time. There's a lot of things I need to do. I need to go back to my philanthropic work. My kids in Africa keep yelling at me to go back and visit. . . . So I was just getting really anxious to do my own things."); id. at 378 ("I honestly am having fun building this kind of transforming company against the incumbent, and enjoying kind of stirring up a new way of doing things. But it's getting to the point that I have to tell myself there are other things I want to do in life.").
Ironically, it was Aruba that stressed Orr's desire to retire in its pre-trial brief and at trial as a means of undermining the reliability of management's projections, which Aruba argued were too aggressive because they assumed that Orr would stay with the Company. See Dkt. 138 at 20-21. Aruba also sought to use Orr's desire to retire to blunt the petitioners' argument that HP's unauthorized discussions with Orr about post-transaction employment undermined the negotiations. As Aruba pitched it, Orr agreed to remain reluctantly. See id. at 44 ("Orr will testify that he planned to retire, but he was motivated by loyalty to his team and a request from HP to stay on."). Once Aruba introduced the retirement theory, the petitioners embraced it as an additional factor that undermined the course of the negotiations, while disputing that Aruba's ability to achieve its projections depended on Orr.
Aruba also helped prove the petitioners' case on this point by focusing at trial on an email exchange from March 7, 2015, between Orr and an Aruba director that discussed why the merger benefitted Aruba's customers and employees, including its salesforce in the field. See JX 535; see also Warmenhoven Tr. 177-83 (discussing JX 535); Orr Tr. 381-97 (same). Aruba argued that this email showed that the HP deal was a good one. Whether the deal was good for these corporate constituencies is a different question than whether it provided fair value for stockholders. What the email did show is that Orr pursued the HP deal (at least in part) because of loyalties to constituencies beyond the stockholders. In the grander scheme of life, I find that commendable. For the narrow purpose of Delaware corporate law, those competing loyalties are factors that a court has to weigh.

See Warmenhoven Tr. 286 ("Dominic [Orr] guaranteed to us that he would go through an orderly transition, that if we found the right person, he would step aside, and we would just hire the person as CEO. And if we couldn't find somebody of that experience, he would stay on for a year and help groom him."); id. at 290 ("Dom [Orr] was a very committed CEO, and independent of the financial implications, he would not have left abruptly. He was a founder of this company. And a founder is . . . it's like having a child. You don't abandon it."); Orr Tr. 458 (testifying that he would not have left without a suitable replacement); JX 326 at 1 (Orr explaining that he wanted to sell at a premium, take care of the employees, and ensure that "the organization and structure is [sic] set up for success and maintaining fun and pride and minimiz[ing] large company pain").

Aruba has argued that Orr could not have been motivated by a desire to retire because he agreed to run the legacy business for HP for a period of time after the acquisition. I think Orr was planning several moves ahead, and he realized that committing to stay on for a period of time after the acquisition would help get the deal done. That, in turn, would bring him closer to returning to a retirement during which he had engaged in a variety of rewarding and commendable pursuits.

As with the issue of competition, the answer on negotiation is that the petitioners proved what they sought to prove, but that is not enough to call into question the deal price for purposes of appraisal. Once again, "[t]he issue in an appraisal is not whether a negotiator has extracted the highest possible bid. Rather, the key inquiry is whether the dissenters got fair value and were not exploited." "[F]air value is just that, 'fair.' It does not mean the highest possible price that a company might have sold for had Warren Buffett negotiated for it on his best day and the Lenape who sold Manhattan on their worst."

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *24.

The evidence does not convince me that the bankers, Orr, the Aruba Board, and the stockholders who approved the transaction all accepted a deal price that left a portion of Aruba's fundamental value on the table. Perhaps different negotiators could have extracted a greater share of the synergies from HP in the form of a higher deal price. Maybe if Orr had been less eager, or if Qatalyst had not been relegated to the back room, then HP would have opened at $24 per share. Perhaps with a brash Qatalyst banker leading the negotiations, unhampered by the Autonomy incident, Aruba might have negotiated more effectively and gotten HP above $25 per share. An outcome along these lines would have resulted in HP sharing a greater portion of the anticipated synergies with Aruba's stockholders. It would not have changed Aruba's standalone value. Hence, it would not have affected Aruba's fair value for purposes of an appraisal.

3. Deducting Synergies

Under Dell and DFC, the deal price in this case has substantial probative value. But the evidence shows that the deal generated significant synergies. Under the DFC decision, it is to be assumed that HP shared some of those with Aruba's stockholders. To derive an estimate of fair value, the court must exclude "any synergies or other value expected from the merger giving rise to the appraisal proceeding itself."

DFC, 172 A.3d at 372; see also Dunmire v. Farmers & Merchs. Bancorp of W. Penn., Inc., 2016 WL 6651411, at *8 n.95 (Del. Ch. Nov. 10, 2016) (surveying academic literature); EV3, 2011 WL 704409, at *10 ("In an arm's-length, synergistic transaction, the deal price generally will exceed fair value because target fiduciaries bargain for a premium that includes . . . a share of the anticipated synergies . . . .").

Golden Telecom Trial, 993 A.2d at 507.

The parties agree that it is not possible to determine with precision what portion of the final deal price reflects synergy value. The respondent's expert conceded that "[t]he percentage of synergies actually paid by HP to Aruba cannot be accurately measured."

Dages Opening Report ¶ 68.

Delaware decisions have recognized the difficulties inherent in quantifying synergies. Despite these difficulties, this court has used a deal-price-less-synergies metric. In Union Illinois, Chief Justice Strine, then a Vice Chancellor, started with the deal consideration of $10.20 per share. He then discounted that figure by 13% to reflect the synergies captured by the seller, basing that figure on the opinion of the respondent's valuation expert, and also citing the fairness opinion of the seller's financial advisor, which "had mid-range synergy assumptions of 15%-20% for the synergy value that would be shared" with the seller.

See, e.g., Montgomery Cellular Hldg. Co., Inc. v. Dobler, 880 A.2d 206, 221 (Del. 2005) ("The Court of Chancery was unable precisely to quantify those 'deal-making' synergies, because [the respondent] did not present any reliable evidence at trial of what those synergies were worth."); ACP Master, Ltd. v. Sprint Corp., 2017 WL 3421142, at *31 (Del. Ch. July 21, 2017) (recounting respondent synergy estimates, noting that "[o]ther synergy estimates were higher still," and concluding that, "[i]f the court relied on Clearwire's deal price, it would have to determine the value of those synergies and back them out"); Ramtron, 2015 WL 4540443, at *26 (acknowledging that the "[p]etitioner's approach may understate the net synergies" but nonetheless adopting it because "it better conforms to the evidence adduced at trial than [the respondent's] position").

Union Ill., 847 A.2d at 353 n.27, 364.

Id. at 353 n.26.

In the Highfields case, Vice Chancellor Lamb gave 75% weight to a deal-price-less-synergies metric. The transaction price was $31 per share. The respondent's expert opined that the deal price incorporated shared synergies equal to 25% of the deal price, or $7.75 per share. The court rejected this estimate because it relied, in part, on a discounted cash flow analysis that the expert had declined to rely on when rendering his other valuation opinions. The court found more credible an analysis prepared by the acquirer, which estimated the lower end of shared synergies at $9.54 per share. Vice Chancellor Lamb regarded this estimate as too high, because it undervalued the acquired company in certain respects. After correcting the acquirer's estimate to account for the undervaluation, Vice Chancellor Lamb concluded that the deal price incorporated synergies of $4.12 per share. That figure worked out to a deduction of 13%, the same number used in Union Illinois.

Highfields, 939 A.2d at 61.

Id. at 60-62.

In this case, the HP deal team anticipated $1.41 billion of synergies. McKinsey projected $1.555 billion in synergies. Barclays' figure was $1.5 billion. McKinsey was an outside consulting firm hired to vet the HP deal team's calculation, adding some credence to its view. This decision therefore uses McKinsey's figure. Aruba's expert drew on a March 2013 study by the Boston Consulting Group which suggested that, on average, sellers collect 31% of the capitalized value of synergies, with the seller's share varying widely from 6% to 51%. Using these figures, the range of synergy value shared in the deal could run from $93 million at the low end to $793 million at the high end. The deal price implied a value for Aruba of $2.651 billion. Using the low-end synergy deduction of $93 million implies a standalone value of $2.558 billion, or $21.08 per share. Using the high-end synergy deduction of $793 million implies a standalone value of $1.858 billion, or $15.32 per share. The midpoint is a standalone value of $2.208 billion or $18.20 per share. Recognizing that it would be arbitrary to import the 13% synergy figure used in both Union Illinois and Highfields, that percentage nevertheless implies a standalone value of $2.306 billion or $19.06 per share.

See Dages Opening Report ¶¶ 64-67.

See Highfields, 939 A.2d at 61 & n.87 (crediting synergy estimations included in a study that "was not of the typically skewed, buy-side variety: rather, it was an objective study created by a team of actuaries whose professional standards require neutrality" and noting the study "stands in contrast to the often biased valuation work presented to opposing boards by investment bankers representing a particular company").

Dages Opening Report ¶ 68.

Id. ¶ 67.

Because I am inclined to think that Aruba's representatives bargained less effectively than they might have, I tend to think that they obtained a relatively low share of the synergies from HP. This would indicate that they obtained fewer synergies than the midpoint range and imply a standalone value north of $18.20 per share. Having no way to gauge the marginal impact of their ineffectiveness, this decision uses $18.20 per share as the valuation indication for the deal price less synergies.

C. The Experts' Analyses

Both sides submitted opinions from valuation experts. Both experts used the discounted cash flow methodology to value Aruba. Both experts believed that the discounted cash flow methodology provided the best approach for determining the fair value of the Company. The respondent's expert, Kevin Dages, said so explicitly: "It is my opinion that Aruba's standalone fair value is most accurately measured using a [discounted cash flow] analysis based on the Management Projections." The petitioners' expert, Paul Marcus, expressed his view implicitly by relying exclusively on the discounted cash flow approach.

Dages Opening Report ¶ 129; accord Dages Tr. 782 ("Q. You are all in on a DCF. Right? A. I think that's fair."); id. ("I looked at other values, but the opinion was always stated, and has always been stated, at the beginning as being based on DCF.").

Marcus Opening Report ¶ 9 ("I determined the fair value of Aruba's stock as of May 18, 2015 (the 'valuation date') by performing a discounted cash flow ('DCF') valuation.").

The discounted cash flow methodology is a valuation technique that the financial community generally accepts and that this court frequently uses in appraisal proceedings. "While the particular assumptions underlying its application may always be challenged in any particular case, the validity of [the discounted cash flow] technique qua valuation methodology is no longer open to question." It is a "standard" method that "gives life to the finance principle that firms should be valued based on the expected value of their future cash flows, discounted to present value in a manner that accounts for risk."

See generally Jesse A. Finkelstein & John D. Hendershot, Appraisal Rights in Mergers & Consolidations, 38-5th C.P.S. §§ IV(H)(3), V.E. (BNA) [hereinafter Appraisal Rights].

Pinson v. Campbell-Taggart, Inc., 1989 WL 17438, at *8 n.11 (Del. Ch. Feb. 28, 1989).

Andaloro v. PFPC Worldwide, Inc., 2005 WL 2045640, at *9 (Del. Ch. Aug. 19, 2005) (Strine, V.C.).

The DCF model entails three basic components: an estimation of net cash flows that the firm will generate and when, over some period; a terminal or residual value equal to the future value, as of the end of the projection period, of the firm's cash flows beyond the projection period; and finally a cost of capital with which to discount to a present value both the projected net cash flows and the estimated terminal or residual value.
The Delaware Supreme Court has recently cautioned that "[a]lthough widely considered the best tool for valuing companies when there is no credible market information and no market check, [discounted cash flow] valuations involve many inputs—all subject to disagreement by well-compensated and highly credentialed experts—and even slight differences in these inputs can produce large valuation gaps."

In re Radiology Assocs., Inc. Litig., 611 A.2d 485, 490 (Del. Ch. 1991) (quoting Technicolor, 1990 WL 161084, at *7).

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *28

1. Marcus's Valuation Opinion

Marcus used a discounted cash flow analysis to opine that the Company's fair value at closing was $32.57 per share. His model generally adhered to the valuation literature and the teachings of the Delaware courts. From a methodological perspective, his model appears sound.

As a source of estimated future cash flows, "Delaware law clearly prefers valuations based on contemporaneously prepared management projections because management ordinarily has the best first-hand knowledge of a company's operations." Marcus used the February Projections, which covered the fiscal years 2015-2017. The February Projections had their roots in management's three-year plan, prepared in the ordinary course of business and with input from the Aruba Board. Management completed an iteration of its three-year plan in summer 2014. Management updated the plan in October 2014. In February 2015, management revised the plan to reflect intervening results and to adopt more conservative assumptions. To cover the final two years of his projection period, Marcus used an extension of the February Projections that Qatalyst prepared working in conjunction with Aruba management. Qatalyst used the same projections as the basis for the fairness opinion that it delivered to the Aruba Board. Aruba also used the same projections in the proxy statement for the deal. Marcus adopted management's estimates for the cost of stock-based compensation and Aruba's tax rates.

Doft & Co. v. Travelocity.com Inc., 2004 WL 1152338, at *5 (Del. Ch. May 20, 2004); see also Cede & Co. v. Technicolor, Inc., 2003 WL 23700218, at *7 (Del. Ch. Dec. 31, 2003) ("When management projections are made in the ordinary course of business, they are generally deemed reliable. Experts who then vary from management forecasts should proffer legitimate reasons for such variance.") (footnote omitted)), rev'd in part, aff'd in part, 884 A.2d 26 (Del. 2005); Gray v. Cytokine Pharmasciences, Inc., 2002 WL 853549, at *8 (Del. Ch. Apr. 25, 2002) (finding "litigation-driven projections to be unreliable" because "[a]ny other result would condone allowing a company's management or board of directors to disavow their own data in order to justify a lower valuation in an appraisal proceeding").

JX 233 at 1 (minutes from meeting where projections presented showing finance team accompanied presentation with "third party analyst data regarding the enterprise wireless LAN market growth rates for the last three years," "compared the Company's revenue growth rates to the market growth rate," and "presented financial scenarios and explained the assumptions underlying each scenario" during which "Board members asked questions, provided feedback and discussion ensued"); see also Warmenhoven Tr. 223-24 (discussing process by which Aruba Board reviewed and "chose to accept" the February Projections).

See Warmenhoven Tr. 219-20; id. at 313-14 (confirming Galvin prepared the June Plan "in the spring of 2014, as part of the normal operations" of the Company); Galvin Tr. 553-54 (discussing development of "top-down" projections incorporating "broader strategic assumptions" discussed by the Aruba Board regularly at the "June meeting").

See JX 297 at 2 (email from Galvin to member of the finance team); JX 315 at 1 (email from Galvin to Qatalyst banker conveying early draft of the October Projections); see also Warmenhoven Tr. 314-15 (discussing Aruba's ordinary process of preparing a yearly operating plan in September); Galvin Tr. 586 (acknowledging the September figures adjusted margins, reflecting "[t]he overall impacts" of Project Greyhound).

See Marcus Opening Report ¶¶ 209-217 (explaining reliance on February Projections); see also Warmenhoven Tr. 220-22 (discussing how and why the finance team made the projections more conservative); Galvin Tr. 558-563 (discussing process of extending ordinary course, six-month budgeting projections out to three years to create February Projections).

See Marcus Opening Report ¶ 217; Warmenhoven Tr. 358 (referring to the added two years as "a linear extrapolation"); Galvin Tr. 558-59 (testifying the February Projections initially went out three years "[a]nd then ultimately until 2020, yes"); Dages Tr. 734 (discussing "the extensions that were done with Qatalyst to take it out to 2020").

See Marcus Opening Report ¶ 221; Galvin Tr. 560 (confirming February Projections used by bankers).

Proxy at 63-64; Orr Tr. 529 (confirming approved projections to be included in the proxy and shared with Qatalyst).

See Marcus Opening Report ¶¶ 218-220.

The Company had projected a tax rate of 4% for 2015 and 2016 and 25% thereafter. See JX 475 at 1 (email from Galvin to Qatalyst suggesting "I would do 4% thr[ough] 17; then do 25% thereafter"). Management attributed the rate to the Company's stockpile of valuable net-operating loss credits or "NOLs" from its early, pre-profit days. Due to those credits, the Company had a cash tax rate of only 3.2% and 3.1% in 2013 and 2014, respectively. The Company anticipated it had enough credits remaining to continue paying low taxes through at least 2016. JX 506 at 1 (internal email summarizing available net-operating loss credits and approximate use rates as of February 2015); see also JX 895 at 93 (2014 10-K: "As of July 1, 2014, the Company's federal loss carryforwards for income tax purposes were approximately $131 million with expiration dates starting in 2028."). Based on this evidence, Marcus adopted the Company's estimates. See Marcus Opening Report Ex. 7-1.
Aruba instructed Qatalyst to use the same tax figures that Marcus ultimately adopted. See JX 654 (Qatalyst working spreadsheet indicating Galvin provided tax rates); Marcus Tr. 46-47; Galvin Tr. 622.

The projections resulted in Aruba having a high compound annual growth rate ("CAGR") of 10% at the end of the projection period. To normalize Aruba's high growth and transition the Company into a steady state, Marcus added a second, five-year stage to create a three-step discounted cash flow model. During the added second stage, he stepped down the growth rate to reach his terminal, third-stage growth rate of 3.5% per year. Delaware decisions and the valuation literature support this approach. Like Marcus, HP used a three-stage discounted cash flow method when valuing Aruba.

Marcus Opening Report ¶ 222.

See, e.g., DFC, 172 A.3d at 380 ("Indeed, if the record unambiguously supported the proposition that DFC was to continue a new spurt of growth past 2018, it would have been more appropriate to project out to a point where steady-state growth began. By doing that, the appraiser would have to assess with discipline the next period after the projections end and also the potential that the period might be negative, as well as that another period of above-market growth might be followed by a terminal growth rate more like inflation than the risk-free rate." (footnote omitted)); Prescott Gp. Small Cap, L.P. v. Coleman Co., Inc., 2004 WL 2059515, at *29 (Del. Ch. Sept. 8, 2004) (Jacobs, J.) ("At the time of the merger, Coleman was projecting a 16% growth in sales for year 2002, which represented a return to Coleman's prior operating levels. Dr. Kursh utilized a three stage model because he did not believe a 16% growth rate was sustainable long-term." (footnote omitted)); Robert W. Holthausen & Mark E. Zmijewski, Corporate Valuation Theory, Evidence & Practice 216 (2014) ("We would prepare detailed year-by-year forecasts for the company until the company reaches steady state. You may need to value a company's cash flows for five years, ten years, or longer if the company is far from becoming a stable mature company as of the valuation date."); Shannon P. Pratt & Alina V. Niculita, Valuing a Business 219 (5th ed. 2008) ("The appropriate length of the forecast period should be until that variability stops; at the point in time that the company expects normalized or level growth, the terminal value is calculated.").

See Johansson Dep. 40 (testifying that, in valuing a company, HP "want[s] to create a model that gets you to like a steady state . . . . [T]ypically, the companies we look at, ten years is kind of appropriate . . . . So we tend to do a ten-year DCF just to get to that steady state.").

Marcus calculated Aruba's weighted average cost of capital ("WACC") using the capital asset pricing model ("CAPM"). "Under CAPM, the cost of equity capital is the risk-free rate of return plus the subject company's risk. The subject company's risk is determined by multiplying the equity risk premium for the market by the company's beta." Marcus used a risk-free rate of 2.75%, based on the twenty-year U.S. Treasury maturity rate, and a supply-side equity risk premium of 6.19%. Marcus drew these figures from reliable sources, and Dages used the same risk-free rate and a virtually identical supply-side equity risk premium. Marcus calculated a beta for Aruba of 0.91, which he derived by giving one-third weight to Aruba's two-year, weekly, raw beta (0.81) and two-thirds weight to the two-year, weekly, raw, unlevered betas of a group of peer companies (1.11). Court of Chancery precedent supports the blended approach, and the valuation literature supports the selection of a two-year period for Aruba. He then added the fifth-decline size premium. These calculations resulted in a 10% WACC.

In calculating his WACC, Marcus used an all-equity capital structure. He noted, however, that evidence in the record suggested that Aruba would have issued $300 million in convertible debt if HP had not made its approach. See, e.g., PTO ¶ 51, JX 224 (Aruba Board subcommittee minutes); JX 325 (email from Galvin relaying conversation with Barclays banker wherein banker suggested executing the convertible offering). The debt would have reduced Aruba's WACC and been a positive signal to the equity markets. Marcus Opening Report ¶ 223. The decision to maintain Aruba's all-equity capital structure could be seen as a valuation consequence that resulted from the expectation of the merger, although one that had a negative effect on Aruba's stockholders by depriving them of the value generated by a lower-cost capital structure. Cf. 8 Del. C. § 262(h) (instructing Court of Chancery to exclude "any element of value arising from the accomplishment or expectation of the merger"). The petitioners have not made this argument, so this decision does not consider it.

In re Emerging Commc'ns, Inc. S'holders Litig., 2004 WL 1305745, at *16 (Del. Ch. May 3, 2004) (Jacobs, J.).

Marcus Opening Report ¶ 225.

See Dages Opening Report ¶¶ 117, 124.

Marcus Opening Report ¶¶ 226-231.

See Merion Capital, L.P. v. 3M Cogent, Inc., 2013 WL 3793896, at *18 (Del. Ch. July 8, 2013) ("[O]ne can 'smooth' beta by adjusting historical beta by a market beta of 1, using a 1/3 weighting factor for the market and a 2/3 weighting for the subject company's beta . . . ."); Golden Telecom Trial, 993 A.2d at 524 ("I find that a beta that gives 2/3 weight to the Bloomberg historic raw beta of 1.32 and 1/3 weight to the 1.24 industry beta is the best approach to this DCF analysis.").

Holthausen & Zmijewski, supra, at 300 ("Using more recent data might better reflect a company's current (and more forward-looking) systematic risk."); Tim Koller, Marc Goedhart & David Wessels, Valuation: Measuring and Managing the Value of Companies 247 (5th ed. 2010) (noting that "changes in corporate strategy or capital structure often lead to changes in risk for stockholders" and that, where that occurs, "a long estimation period would place too much weight on irrelevant data"); Shannon P. Pratt & Roger J. Grabowski, Cost of Capital: Applications and Examples 208 (5th ed. 2014) (noting that five-years is more common but where "business characteristics change during the sampling period . . . it may be more appropriate to use a shorter sampling period. However, as the sampling period used is reduced, the accuracy of the estimate is generally reduced."); id. at 224 (recommending that "[i]f the underlying fundamentals of the business have changed, a more recent period should be used in developing a beta estimate"). Aruba had grown significantly during the years preceding the merger. See PTO ¶ 77. Aruba's expert agreed that he typically uses a two-year weakly raw beta when calculating WACC. Dages Tr. 793; Dages Dep. 432.

Marcus Opening Report ¶ 230. "In addition to the equity risk premium, an equity size premium generally is added to the company's cost of equity in the valuation of smaller companies to account for the higher rate of return demanded by investors to compensate for the greater risk associated with small company equity." Gearreald v. Just Care, Inc., 2012 WL 1569818, at *10 (Del. Ch. Apr. 30, 2012). Dages disputed the applicability of a size premium at all because, "in [his] experience, a size premium is rarely applied to mid- or larger-cap companies" and "Aruba did not share the characteristics that researchers have hypothesized for returns in excess of what is predicted by the CAPM." Dages Rebuttal Report ¶ 32. He further argued that Aruba properly belonged in the sixth rather than fifth decile. Id.

Dages used a WACC of 11%. Dages observed that all three deal advisors and two research analysts used higher WACCs. Dages Opening Report Ex. 18; Dages Rebuttal Report ¶ 31.

To calculate value for the terminal period, Marcus used the Gordon Growth Model. "To calculate terminal value using the Gordon Growth Model, the Court must select a long-term growth rate, i.e., the expected growth rate of free cash flows into perpetuity." As noted, Marcus selected a perpetuity growth rate of 3.5%. He believed it was reasonable to assume that Aruba would grow at the rate of the overall economy, but to be conservative he selected a growth rate approximately at the midpoint of the risk-free rate (2.75%) and nominal GDP growth rate, as predicted by reliable, oft-cited studies (4.3%).

Marcus Opening Report ¶ 235.

3M, 2013 WL 3793896, at *21.

Marcus Opening Report ¶¶ 232-235. Marcus did not clarify why he adopted the risk-free rate rather than the projected rate of inflation as the floor for his terminal growth rate. As discussed in addressing Dages's report below, some of this court's precedent suggests adopting the risk-free rate as a ceiling for a company's long-term sustainable growth rate. This court's precedents support adopting the rate of inflation as a floor for a company's long-term growth rate. See Golden Telecom Trial, 993 A.2d at 511-12 ("A viable company should grow at least at the rate of inflation and . . . the rate of inflation is the floor for a terminal value estimate for a solidly profitable company that does not have an identifiable risk of insolvency."); see also Owen v. Cannon, 2015 WL 3819204, at *25 (Del. Ch. June 17, 2015) ("I find that it is appropriate under Golden Telecom to calculate the terminal growth rate as a premium to inflation."). The distinction does not alter the outcome in this case, and this decision expresses no view on the issue.

Marcus sensitized his valuation for discount rates of 9.5% to 10.5% and terminal growth rates of 3.0% to 4.0%, generating a valuation range for $29.16 to $36.93. The midpoint, based on a discount rate of 10% and a terminal growth rate of 3.5%, was $32.57.

Marcus Opening Report ¶ 236.

My primary concerns with Marcus's opinion are his beta and the contrast between his valuation and market indicators. Marcus's raw and blended betas were both lower than one, indicating that Aruba, a relatively young and growing technology company, exhibited less volatility than the market as a whole. Although the data supported the low beta, no one could offer a good explanation as to why the number was so low. Marcus's beta of 0.91 also fell roughly 20% below the median two-year adjusted beta of companies in Aruba's peer group and approximately 35% below Aruba's five-year adjusted weekly beta. That said, Aruba's low beta was not unique. The bankers' fairness presentations identified other networking and WiFi companies that had betas of less than 1.

Dages Tr. 747; see also Pratt & Grabowski, supra, at 194 ("Many high-tech companies are good examples of stocks with high betas. . . . The classic example of a low-beta stock would be a utility that has not diversified into riskier activities.").

See, e.g., Dages Tr. 790-91 ("I don't see a basis for getting comfortable with a beta that is that low given this company, its position in the industry, and what I've heard about the challenges it's facing. Especially when I look at the peers and they are all up over 1. And I look at them, and they are well over 1 in a longer time period.").

See Dages Opening Report ¶¶ 118-19. See generally Dages Rebuttal Report ¶¶ 26-31 (criticizing Marcus's beta).

See JX 802 at 25; JX 809 at 31.

Marcus's valuation outcome diverged significantly from market indications. His valuation of $32.57 is

• approximately 32% higher than the deal price of $24.67;

• approximately 39% higher than the mean of the last batch of unaffected analyst price targets at $23.4;
• approximately 21% above the mean of the midpoints of the final valuations prepared by all three advisors at $26.57; and

• nearly double Aruba's thirty-day average unaffected market price of $17.13 per share.
Despite its seemingly sound methodology, these market indicators combine to create significant doubt regarding the reliability of the Marcus discounted cash flow analysis and its resulting valuation.

Marcus Opening Report Ex. 3-1.

See JX 806 at 14 (final Barclays valuation); JX 811 at 19 (final Qatalyst valuation); JX 812 at 14 (final Evercore valuation).

2. Dages's Valuation Opinion

Dages rendered several different valuation opinions. They produced relatively stable outputs but changed substantially in their inputs. Dages also made a significant judgment call by selecting a WACC from a menu of possibilities, rather than calculating a beta to generate a WACC as contemplated by CAPM.

In his opening report, Dages opined that the standalone fair value of Aruba was $19.85 per share, which he derived using a discounted cash flow methodology. Like Marcus, Dages used the February Projections with the two-year extension prepared by Qatalyst with management's input. Unlike Marcus, who used management estimates for stock-based compensation and tax rates, Dages used a stock-based compensation figure from Barclays, and his own estimate of Aruba's effective tax rate. Despite recognizing the issue raised by Aruba's high growth rate at the end of the projection period, Dages used a traditional two-stage model rather than a three-stage model. For his terminal value, Dages explained the principles used when selecting a long-term growth rate in much the same terms as Marcus, but then chose the risk-free rate (2.75%) because "some financial economists caution that the risk-free rate . . . should serve as the ceiling for a stable, long-term growth rate" and this court had used that rate in "a recent opinion."

Dages Opening Report ¶¶ 7, 56.

See id. ¶¶ 89-96; Dages Rebuttal Report ¶ 4; see also Dages Dep. 311 (describing the February projections with the two-year extension as the "best projections" for Aruba); accord Dages Tr. 733.

See Dages Opening Report ¶¶ 98-106 (describing the stock-based compensation figures he generated).

See id. ¶ 115 (using tax rate of 30%). Dages stated in his report that "[t]he 30.0 percent tax rate is based on the effective tax rate used by Aruba in the Management Projections." Id. At trial, he admitted that this was an error. See Dages Tr. 732-33; 812-15.

Dages Tr. 802-05.

See Dages Opening Report ¶¶ 108-109.

See id. ¶ 110. Dages's report did not cite the financial economists or the opinion. Presumably, he was referring to the DFC trial-level opinion, where he also served as an expert. There, Chancellor Bouchard adopted the risk-free rate as a ceiling in reliance on Dages's identical suggestion "that some financial economists view the risk-free rate as the ceiling for a stable, longterm growth rate." DFC Trial, 2016 WL 3753123, at *17. In that case, Dages had also acknowledged that "one suggested ceiling for a company's perpetuity growth rate is nominal GDP." Id. at *18; see also Golden Telecom Trial, 993 A.2d at 511 ("Generally, once an industry has matured, a company will grow at a steady rate that is roughly equal to the rate of nominal GDP growth."). Dages conceded that a 4.5% perpetuity growth rate, substantially above the 3.14% risk-free rate calculated in that case, was "at the high end of the reasonable range of long-term growth rates." DFC Trial, 2016 WL 3753123, at *18. On appeal, the Delaware Supreme Court stated that the risk-free rate "is viewed to be the ceiling for a stable, long-term growth rate." DFC, 172 A.3d at 383. The idea that a company in a steady state will grow more or less in line with the average rate of the broader economy has intuitive appeal. See 3M, 2013 WL 3793896, at *21 (quoting Golden Telecom for the proposition that "the rate of inflation is the floor for a terminal value" and noting that "a terminal growth rate should not be greater than the nominal growth rate for the United States economy"). Because the experts did not develop the issue further, and because resolving it is not necessary to decide this case, this decision expresses no opinion on the matter.

For his discount rate, Dages started out using CAPM to develop a WACC. He used the same risk-free rate as Marcus (2.75%) and a supply-side equity risk premium that was substantially similar to Marcus's (6.21%). On the issues of a beta and size premium, however, Dages punted. He described a variety of possible betas, including (i) raw and adjusted betas for Aruba derived using two years of weekly measurements, five years of weekly measurements, and five years of monthly measurements, and (ii) raw and adjusted betas for peer companies derived using the same measuring periods. Rather than selecting a beta, Dages used the various candidates to generate nine possible WACCs. He then added into the mix the WACCs used by the three financial advisors and WACCs from two analysts, for a total of fourteen possibilities. After surveying these, he chose a WACC of 11%. His WAAC implied a beta of 1.33. This court has criticized similarly unstructured approaches to valuation inputs.

See Dages Opening Report ¶ 117.

See id. ¶ 124.

See id. ¶¶ 118-122.

Id. Ex. 18.

Id. ¶ 127.

Dages Rebuttal Report ¶ 4.

See In re Orchard Enters., Inc., 2012 WL 2923305, at *17 (Del. Ch. July 18, 2012) (Strine, C.) (expressing the court's preference for "the more academically and empirically-driven CAPM model when that can be applied responsibly" and noting that it involves "less (but still more than comfortable) amounts of subjectivity"); Del. Open MRI, 898 A.2d at 338 (questioning the use of the build-up method with its concept of "company-specific risk" and observing "[t]he calculation of a company specific risk is highly subjective and often is justified as a way of taking into account competitive and other factors that endanger the subject company's ability to achieve its projected cash flows. In other words, it is often a back-door method of reducing estimated cash flows rather than adjusting them directly. To judges, the company specific risk premium often seems like the device experts employ to bring their final results into line with their clients' objectives, when other valuation inputs fail to do the trick."); Andaloro, 2005 WL 2045640, at *12 n.49 (criticizing expert who "spiraled" into a terminal growth rate "through an incomprehensible 'iterative process'" and finding that "[r]ather than a reasoned exercise in applied social science, [the expert] appears to have channeled inspiration, more like a great songwriter than a valuation expert").

After I issued an evidentiary ruling precluding Dages from rendering an opinion on stock-based compensation, Dages changed course and relied at trial on a set of projections that he had created himself using industry growth rates and referenced in a footnote in his opening report. When he ran his discounted cash flow model with those projections and management's figures for stock-based compensation expense, his model generated a value of $19.45 per share, forty cents below his original opinion. At trial, Dages revised his view on Aruba's tax expenses and agreed with management's use of a 4% tax rate for 2015 and 2016, although he continued to endorse the use of a 30% tax rate for subsequent years rather than management's rate of 25%. This modification added thirty cents per share to his valuation, resulting in a figure of $19.75 per share. Serendipitously, that result fell just ten cents below the valuation in his opening report, although reached using substantially different inputs. This is the fair value figure that Aruba endorsed at post-trial argument.

Dages Tr. 760-61 ("Q. So to be clear, your opinion, when you originally opined, was the February revenue projections; right? A. Correct."); id. at 767 ("Q. So you didn't just swap out the Dell'Oro projected growth rates for the industry for management's. You created your own industry projections. A. Correct."); id. at 772 ("Q. Now, in fact, you don't have any expertise that would allow you to determine whether Dell'Oro's industrywide growth rates are a reasonable proxy for Aruba's expected future performance, do you? A. No. No independent expertise, no.").

Dages Tr. 751, 813. In light of other evidence in the record, the cash tax rate is more persuasive. See Galvin Dep. 296 (stating that management provided the cash tax rate); JX 548 (Qatalyst spreadsheet showing management's cash tax rates); JX 654 (Qatalyst projections using management's cash tax rate); see also Dages Tr. 815 (testifying that cash tax rate is typically more accurate than effective tax rate).

Dages's final opinion of $19.75 per share comported with market evidence by falling between the unaffected market price and the deal price. Its methodological underpinnings, however, provided cause for concern, as did the meandering route by which Dages arrived at this figure.

D. Weighing the Valuation Methodologies

This decision has discussed each of the relevant methods of valuation that the parties presented. Under the statute, the court must make a point estimate of fair value measured in dollars and cents. When determining fair value, "[t]he Court of Chancery must exercise its considerable discretion while also explaining, with reference to the economic facts before it and corporate finance principles, why it is according a certain weight to a certain indicator of value."

The forceful discussion of the efficient capital markets hypothesis in Dell and DFC indicates that Aruba's unaffected market price is entitled to substantial weight.

[C]orporate finance theory reflects a belief that if an asset—such as the value of a company as reflected in the trading value of its stock—can be subject to close examination and bidding by many humans with an incentive to estimate its future cash flows value, the resulting collective judgment as to value is likely to be highly informative . . . .
"Market prices are typically viewed superior to other valuation techniques because, unlike, e.g., a single person's discounted cash flow model, the market price should distill the collective judgment of the many based on all the publicly available information about a given company and the value of its shares." "[I]n many circumstances a property interest is best valued by the amount a buyer will pay for it" and "a well-informed, liquid trading market will provide a measure of fair value superior to any estimate the court could impose."

DFC, 172 A.3d at 370; accord Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *17 (explaining that, when a market is efficient, "a company's stock price reflects the judgments of many stockholders about the company's future prospects, based on public filings, industry information, and research conducted by equity analysts. In these circumstances, a mass of investors quickly digests all publicly available information about a company, and in trading the company's stock, recalibrates its price to reflect the market's adjusted, consensus valuation of the company" (internal quotation marks and footnotes omitted)).

DFC, 172 A.3d at 369-70; see also Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *17 ("[T]he price produced by an efficient market is generally a more reliable assessment of fair value than the view of a single analyst, especially an expert witness who caters her valuation to the litigation imperatives of a well-heeled client.").

Applebaum, 812 A.2d at 890 (Del. 2002); see also Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *15 n.108 (citing Applebaum); DFC, 172 A.3d at 369 & n.116 (quoting Applebaum).

In this case, because Aruba's shares "were widely traded on a public market based upon a rich information basis," the fair value of the petitioners' shares "would, to an economist, likely be best reflected by the prices at which their shares were trading as of the merger." Aruba had "a deep base of public shareholders" and "highly active trading," so "the price at which its shares trade is informative of fair value." The unaffected thirty-day average market price of Aruba's stock was $17.13 per share.

Id. at 373.

Dell and DFC teach that the deal price is also entitled to substantial weight. "In economics, the value of something is what it will fetch in the market. That is true of corporations, just as it is true of gold." For a court to give weight to the deal price, it need not be the most reliable evidence of the Company's value as a going concern. This court has authority "to determine, in its discretion, that the deal price is the most reliable evidence of fair value . . . , and that's especially so in cases . . . where things like synergy gains or minority stockholder discounts are not contested."

Id. at 368-69 (footnote omitted).

Id. at 364.

Id. at 367; see also Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *16 ("In fact, the record as distilled by the trial court suggests that the deal price deserved heavy, if not dispositive, weight.").

The deal price in this case resulted from an arm's-length transaction involving a publicly traded company without a controlling stockholder. The deal price in this case contained synergies, so it logically exceeded fair value. There is also the fact that the petitioners failed to identify a bidder who would pay more than HP. "Fair value entails at minimum a price some buyer is willing to pay . . . ." Taken together, these propositions indicate that the deal price in this case operates as a ceiling for fair value.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *21.

The Dell and DFC decisions recognize that a deal price may include synergies and endorse deriving an indication of fair value from the deal price by deducting synergies. In this case, the evidence shows that the deal generated significant synergies. Using the low-end synergy range implies a standalone value of $21.08 per share. Using the high-end synergy range implies a standalone value of $15.32 per share. This decision has adopted the midpoint of $18.20 per share as its deal-price-less-synergies value.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *13; DFC, 172 A.3d at 371.

This decision does not give any weight to the discounted cash flow analyses. As in Dell, "this appraisal case does not present the classic scenario in which there is reason to suspect that market forces cannot be relied upon to ensure fair treatment of the minority." Discounted cash flow models are "often used in appraisal proceedings when the respondent company was not public or was not sold in an open market check."

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *26.

DFC, 172 A.3d at 369 n.118.

The reason for that is not that an economist wouldn't consider the best estimate of a private company's value to be the price it sold at in an open sale process of which all logical buyers were given full information and an equal opportunity to compete. Rather, the reason is that if such a process did not
occur, corporate finance instructs that the value of the company to potential buyers should be reflected in its ability to generate future cash flows.
"But, a single person's own estimate of the cash flows are just that, a good faith estimate by a single, reasonably informed person to predict the future. Thus, a singular discounted cash flow model is often most helpful when there isn't an observable market price." When market evidence is available, "the Court of Chancery should be chary about imposing the hazards that always come when a law-trained judge is forced to make a point estimate of fair value based on widely divergent partisan expert testimony."

Id.

Id. at 370.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *26.

Marcus's discounted cash flow valuation of $32.57 per share diverged substantially from market indications. His figure is nearly double Aruba's thirty-day average unaffected market price of $17.13. It is approximately 32% higher than the deal price of $24.67 per share. In a transaction involving a financial buyer that could be expected to generate few if any combinatorial synergies, the Delaware Supreme Court recently emphasized the lack of reliability of a discounted cash flow analysis that yielded a result that was 40% over the deal price. The transaction in this case generated substantial synergies.

DFC, 172 A.3d at 362; cf. Lender Processing, 2016 WL 7324170, at *33 ("The proximity between [the discounted cash flow] outcome and the result of the sale process is comforting."); Ancestry.com, 2015 WL 399726, at *23 ("The DCF valuation I have described is close to the market, and gives me comfort that no undetected factor skewed the sales process.").

Dages's initial discounted cash flow valuation of $19.85 and revised discounted cash flow valuation of $19.75 fell nicely between the unaffected market price and the deal price. His figures also landed close to HP's standalone discounted cash flow valuation of $18.98 and Barclay's standalone discounted cash flow valuation of $19.93. The relative lack of methodological rigor in the analysis, however, creates cause for concern about the strategic selection of inputs to channel the result into this range.

The two probative indications of value in this case are the unaffected market price of $17.13 and the deal-price-less-synergies value of approximately $18.20 per share. Using these indicators nevertheless carries conceptual difficulties because "[t]he time for determining the value of a dissenter's shares is the point just before the merger transaction 'on the date of the merger.'" If the value of the corporation changes between the signing of the merger and the closing, the fair value determination must be measured by the "operative reality" of the corporation at the effective time of the merger.

Appraisal Rights, supra, at A-33 (quoting Technicolor I, 542 A.2d at 1187).

Technicolor II, 684 A.2d at 298.

The unaffected market price provides direct evidence of the collective view of market participants as to Aruba's fair value as a going concern during the period before the announcement of the transaction, which could be different than Aruba's fair value as of closing. The same disconnect exists for the deal price, which provides evidence of how the parties to the merger agreement valued Aruba during the price negotiations, which could be different than Aruba's fair value as of closing. Addressing a similar issue in the Union Illinois case, Chief Justice Strine described the temporal gap as a "quibble" and "not a forceful objection," noting that "[t]he negotiation of merger terms always and necessarily precedes consummation." Observing that "[n]othing in the record persuades me that [the company] was more valuable by [closing] than it was when the Merger terms were set," he continued to use the deal price as an indicator of value. Similarly in this case, neither side proved that Aruba's value had changed materially by closing, so this decision sticks with the unaffected market price and the deal price less synergies.

Union Ill., 847 A.2d at 358.

Id.

The difficult question is how to choose between, weigh, or otherwise exercise my discretion non-abusively when evaluating the two probative valuation indications. The unaffected market price provides a direct measure of the collective judgment of numerous market participants about Aruba's value as a going concern. The deal price less synergies provides an indirect measure with two significant sources of uncertainty.

One is the problem of measurement error. Under the traditional view of the efficient capital markets hypothesis, errors are randomly distributed and cancel out. My deal- price-less-synergies figure could have errors at multiple levels. To cite just a few, I may have erred when making my case-specific allocation of synergies to the sell-side. I might have misinterpreted the information that Aruba's expert cited, or that data itself could contain sampling and measurement errors. The size of the original synergy estimates might also be off, as could any number of individual estimates that added up to the overarching estimates. After all, they were necessarily predictions about complex matters. Perhaps errors at one level might counterbalance errors at another, but there is no way to know, and the smaller number of judgments involved (compared to the number of trades generating the market price) makes it more likely that the errors could skew the figure, just like a small and undiversified portfolio can produce extreme results. The Delaware Supreme Court's expressed preference in Dell and DFC for market indicators over discounted cash flow valuations counsels in favor of preferring market indicators over the output of a similarly judgment-laden exercise of backing out synergies.

See Ronald J. Gilson & Reinier H. Kraakman, The Mechanisms of Market Efficiency, 70 Va. L. Rev. 549, 581 (1984). Behavioral economics, noise theory, and chaos theory may provide reasons to question this assumption, but for the reasons already stated, I do not believe that a trial court has the flexibility to disregard the Delaware Supreme Court's framing of the efficient capital markets hypothesis.

Cf. Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *26; DFC, 172 A.3d at 388.

The other difficulty is that my deal-price-less-synergies figure continues to incorporate an element of value resulting from the merger. When an acquirer purchases a widely traded firm, the premium that an acquirer is willing to pay for the entire firm anticipates incremental value both from synergies and from the reduced agency costs that result from unitary (or controlling) ownership. Like synergies, the value created by reduced agency costs results from the transaction and is not part of the going concern value of the firm. The value belongs to the buyer, although the seller may extract a portion of it through negotiations. Eliminating shared synergies therefore only goes part of the way towards eliminating "any element of value arising from the accomplishment or expectation of the merger." A court also must eliminate the share of value that accrues from the reduced agency costs.

See Rationalizing Appraisal, supra, at 1038, 1049.

See Rationalizing Appraisal, supra, at 1023-24, 1038, 1046-54, 1067; Implicit Minority Discount, supra, at 30-36, 52; Fair Value of Cornfields, supra, at 139-41.

See Control Premiums, supra, at 866-71; Rationalizing Appraisal, supra, at 1052-53; Implicit Minority Discount, supra, at 35, 52.

See Rationalizing Appraisal, supra, at 1055 (explaining that, for an acquisition of a widely held firm, "the firm's going concern value can be estimated . . . as the actual purchase price minus synergies minus control value"). Failing to make this adjustment would treat the value of the firm as greater than the aggregated value of individual shares, which is the same analytical misstep reflected in the concept of the implicit minority discount. See Control Premiums, supra, 854-59 (explaining conflict between efficient capital markets hypothesis and implicit minority discount); Implicit Minority Discount, supra, 53 (explaining logical equivalence between correcting for a non-existent implicit minority discount and introducing a "'third-party sale value lite' standard in lieu of the traditional 'proportionate share of going concern value' standard").

For Aruba, using its unaffected market price provides the more straightforward and reliable method for estimating the value of the entity as a going concern. I could strive to reach the same endpoint by backing out shared synergies and a share of value for reduced agency costs, but both steps are messy and provide ample opportunities for error. For Aruba, the unaffected market price provides a direct estimate of the same endpoint. Rather than representing my own fallible determination, it distills "the collective judgment of the many based on all the publicly available information about a given company and the value of its shares." "[T]he price produced by an efficient market is generally a more reliable assessment of fair value than the view of a single analyst," particularly when a trial judge is playing the analyst's role.

See Control Premiums, supra, at 858-59 ("The basic conclusion of the Efficient Capital Markets Hypothesis (ECMH) is that market values of companies' shares traded in competitive and open markets are unbiased estimates of the value of the equity of such firms."); Implicit Minority Discount, supra, at 52 ("Take the case of a publicly traded company that has no controller. Efficient market theory states that the shares of this company trade at the pro rata value of the corporation as a going concern."); id. at 60 ("As a matter of generally accepted financial theory . . . , share prices in liquid and informed markets do generally represent that going concern value . . . ."); see also Rationalizing Appraisal, supra, at 1033-34.

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *17

This approach does not elevate "market value" to the governing standard under the appraisal statute. The governing standard for fair value under the appraisal statute remains the entity's value as a going concern. For Aruba, the unaffected public market price provides the best evidence of its value as a going concern.

In this case, the best evidence of Aruba's fair value as a going concern, exclusive of any value derived from the merger, is its thirty-day average unaffected market price of $17.13 per share. I recognize that no one argued for this result. I also recognize that the resulting award is lower than Aruba's proposed figure of $19.75 per share. That figure relied on its expert's discounted cash flow analysis, which this decision has found unpersuasive.

"When . . . none of the parties establishes a value that is persuasive, the Court must make a determination based on its own analysis." The appraisal statute requires that "the Court shall determine the fair value of the shares." This means that I must reach my own, independent determination of fair value. That determination is $17.13 per share.

Cooper v. Pabst Brewing Co., 1993 WL 208763, at *8 (Del. Ch. June 8, 1993) (citing In re Shell Oil Co., 607 A.2d 1213 (Del. 1992)); accord Del. Open MRI Radiology Assocs. P.A. v. Kessler, 898 A.2d 290, 310-11 (Del. Ch. 2006). See generally Appraisal Rights, supra, at A-89 to A-90 ("If both parties fail to meet the preponderance standard on the ultimate question of fair value, the Court is required under the statute to make its own determination.").

Dell, 2017 WL 6375829, at *13 ("In reality, the burden falls on the trial judge to determine fair value, using all relevant factors." (internal quotation marks and alterations omitted)). --------

III. CONCLUSION

The petitioners are awarded $17.13 per share. The legal rate of interest, compounded quarterly, shall accrue on this amount from the date of closing until the date of payment. The parties shall cooperate in preparing a final order. If the parties identify additional issues that need to be resolved, they shall submit a joint letter within two weeks that explains the issues and recommends a schedule for bringing this case to conclusion, at least at the trial court level.


Summaries of

Verition Partners Master Fund Ltd. v. Aruba Networks, Inc.

COURT OF CHANCERY OF THE STATE OF DELAWARE
Feb 15, 2018
C.A. No. 11448-VCL (Del. Ch. Feb. 15, 2018)
Case details for

Verition Partners Master Fund Ltd. v. Aruba Networks, Inc.

Case Details

Full title:VERITION PARTNERS MASTER FUND LTD. and VERITION MULTI-STRATEGY MASTER FUND…

Court:COURT OF CHANCERY OF THE STATE OF DELAWARE

Date published: Feb 15, 2018

Citations

C.A. No. 11448-VCL (Del. Ch. Feb. 15, 2018)

Citing Cases

Verition Partners Master Fund Ltd. v. Aruba Networks, Inc.

On remand, the Court of Chancery shall enter a final judgment for the petitioners awarding them $ 19.10 per…

In re AOL Inc.

As with deal price, an efficiently derived stock trading price can serve as a check on a fair value analysis.…