From Casetext: Smarter Legal Research

Onebeacon Ins. Co. v. Plant Insulation Co.

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA SAN FRANCISCO DIVISION
Aug 18, 2014
No. C 14-01200 RS (N.D. Cal. Aug. 18, 2014)

Opinion

No. C 14-01200 RS

08-18-2014

ONEBEACON INSURANCE COMPANY, et al. , Appellants, v. PLANT INSULATION CO., et al., Appellees.


ORDER DENYING APPEAL FROM CONFIRMATION OF REVSIED PLAN OF REORGANIZATION

I. INTRODUCTION

This appeal marks the latest chapter in the reorganization of Plant Insulation Company, a Chapter 11 debtor formerly involved in the sale, installation, repair, and distribution of products containing asbestos. The Ninth Circuit rejected Plant's prior reorganization plan (the "Original Plan"), holding the plan failed to comply with 11 U.S.C. § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III), a Bankruptcy Code provision that seeks to ensure a reorganized debtor's future operations are controlled by an asbestos trust formed under § 524(g). The Plan Proponents then formulated and lodged an amended plan (the "Revised Plan"), which was subsequently confirmed by the bankruptcy court. A contingent of Plant's insurers lodged this appeal of the confirmation order, arguing the Revised Plan still violates § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III). For the following reasons, the appeal is denied.

The Plan Proponents consist of Plant, the Official Committee of Unsecured Creditors, and the Futures Representative.

II. BACKGROUND

The factual background of Plant's bankruptcy and Bayside's formation is set out in the prior order confirming the Original Plan. See In re Plant Insulation Co., 485 B.R. 203 (N.D. Cal. 2012) ("Plant II") aff'd, 544 F. App'x 669 (9th Cir. 2013) and rev'd, 734 F.3d 900 (9th Cir. 2013) cert. denied, 134 S. Ct. 1901 (U.S. 2014). That history need not be repeated here.

A. Plan Mechanics

Before addressing the new features of the Revised Plan, which is substantially similar to the Original Plan, a general summary of the Plans' structure is warranted. The Plan provides two avenues for compensating existing and future asbestos injury claimants: (1) from a trust established under § 524(g) ("the Trust"), and (2) by preserving claimants' right to file tort actions against Plant and insurers that refuse to settle such claims (the "Non-Settling Insurers") by making cash contributions to the Trust. The § 524(g) injunction operates to create strong incentives for Plant's remaining insurers to settle their potential liabilities by making cash contributions to the Trust, or else continue to defend asbestos injury claims without any possibility of receiving reimbursement from Plant if its underlying liability policies are ultimately determined to be exhausted. In exchange for such settlement payments, the injunction completely releases so-called Settling Insurers from all claims brought by all parties, including tort claims asserted by asbestos injury claimants, and claims for equitable contribution that might otherwise be brought by Non-Settling Insurers.

Absent specific mention of the Original Plan or the Revised Plan, any general reference in this order to "the Plan" is intended to describe both versions.

The Plan further provides partial payment for general unsecured creditors, including insurers' claims for reimbursement, by setting aside ten percent of all available funds (e.g., insurance settlement proceeds) to the Unsecured Claims Reserve. All other available cash proceeds are transferred to the Trust for reimbursement to asbestos injury claimants. Distributions to those claimants will be made according to established "Trust Distribution Procedures," which enable the Trust's administrators to determine the amount of compensable damages for each claimant as well as the proportion of the Trust's funds that may be paid out to each claimant without depleting payments to future claimants.

Alternatively, under the Plan, asbestos injury claimants retain their right to pursue Plant and Non-Settling Insurers by filing a tort action, subject to several conditions. First, a determination by the Trust as to the validity or sum of compensable claims cannot provide a basis for liability in the courts. Second, if a claimant obtains a judgment against Plant, he or she may file suit (or Direct Action) against the Non-Settling Insurers to determine whether the claim is covered by insurance. Claimants are enjoined from enforcing any such judgment against the Settling Insurers, (reorganized) Bayside, or the officers, directors, or shareholders of either Plant or Bayside. In addition, any such judgment against a Non-Settling Insurer obtained by an asbestos injury claimant must be reduced by the amount previously recovered by the claimant from the Trust. By the same token, a claimant who is fully compensated in such a Direct Action against a Non-Settling Insurer may not seek to recover from the Fund. Finally, a claimant may not proceed with a Direct Action unless he or she agrees in writing that the Non-Settling Insurer may offset from any recovery otherwise available in a final judgment, the amount of equitable contributions (including for defense costs) that would be available to the Non-Settling Insurer from other Settling Insurers, collection of which is enjoined under the Plan. The foregoing deductions to Direct Action judgments are only applicable if the Action goes to trial and leads to a final judgment. In other words, those deductions are not available to the Non-Settling Insurers in asbestos-related cases that are dismissed without any payment to the claimant or settled before judgment.

The Plan also requires the merger of Plant and Bayside, under the latter's name. As part of that transaction, the Trust will invest $2 million in the reorganized Bayside and receive 40 percent of the common stock of the company in exchange, as well as a warrant to purchase an additional 11 percent of shares (thus totaling 51 percent of voting shares). Reorganized Bayside is to assume Plant's responsibilities to its insurers under the latter's liability policies, post-merger.

B. The Ninth Circuit Opinion

A contingent of Non-Settling Insurers appealed this court's order affirming the Original Plan, challenging various of its aspects as violating the U.S. Constitution, the Bankruptcy Code, California law, and rules of equity. While rejecting most of the Insurers' arguments, the Ninth Circuit concluded that the Original Plan had one fatal flaw: it failed to comply with § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III), which specifies that the trust must "own, or by the exercise of rights granted under such plan would be entitled to own if specified contingencies occur, a majority of the voting shares" of the reorganized debtor. The parties refer to this provision as the "control requirement."

The Original Plan provided that the Trust could gain 51% ownership of Bayside in two different ways. First, the Trust could invoke its outstanding warrant to purchase an additional 11% of the shares of Bayside, bringing its ownership to 51%. Importantly, the warrant was tied to the pro rata share price of the Trust's initial $2 million investment in 40% of the company. Accordingly, to exercise its warrant under the Original Plan, the Trust would have been required to pay an additional $1,122,559. Second, the Original Plan required Bayside to provide the Trust with a $250,000 promissory note secured by additional shares in the company. If Bayside defaulted on the note, the Trust would receive enough additional shares to bring the Trust into majority ownership of the company.

The parties disputed whether either contingency satisfied the requirement that the Trust be entitled to own, "if specified contingencies occur," a majority of the voting shares of Bayside. See 11 § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III). Because the statute does not explicitly limit the sort or nature of the contingencies that would satisfy the control requirement, the prior confirmation order concluded that any contingency suffices, so long as some circumstances are provided in the plan that would, through the exercise of rights granted therein, allow the trust to gain majority control of the reorganized debtor. See Plant II, 485 B.R. at 226-27. The Ninth Circuit disagreed, finding that such an interpretation would allow for scenarios where the trust would retain merely an illusory form of prospective "control" of the reorganized debtor:

If "specified contingencies" could include any contingency-such as a meteor hitting the Empire State Building-then the subsection has no content because the plan drafters could write it out of existence at will.
In re Plant Insulation Co., 734 F.3d 900, 915 (9th Cir. 2013) ("Plant III") cert. denied, 134 S. Ct. 1901 (U.S. 2014).

The Ninth Circuit's interpretation of the control requirement grew out of several observations about § 524(g)'s text, design, and history. First, the court emphasized that the language of § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) uses the "key phrase 'voting shares.'" Id. "This is significant," the court noted, "because it signals that this section is about control over the reorganized debtor's future operations." Id. The court also found support in the design of § 524(g) as a whole:

[T]he design of § 524(g) reveals that this subsection is a key piece governing the relationship of the trust to the reorganized debtor. It is one of only four requirements that § 524(g) places on the trust. The other three require the trust: (1) to assume the liabilities of the debtor for asbestos actions; (2) to be at least partially funded by equity in the debtor; and (3) to use trust assets or income to pay asbestos claimants. Read together, these requirements are part of a scheme that ensures that, after the bankruptcy, the trust stands in for the debtor with regard to asbestos claims and the debtor continues to operate its business for the benefit of the trust.
Id. at 916. This design is "thwarted," the court concluded, "if a plan can make control of the debtor effectively impossible." Id.

The court's reading of § 524(g) was also informed by the statute's history. Enacted in 1994, § 524(g) was modeled after the approach taken in the "celebrated" Johns-Manville bankruptcy case. 734 F.3d at 915 (citing Kane v. Johns-Manville Corp., 843 F.2d 636 (2d Cir. 1988)). The Johns-Manville "approach" refers to the realization that, "given the lengthy latency period of asbestos-related diseases, companies facing asbestos risk have no way finally to resolve or even effectively estimate their exposure." 734 F.3d 905-06. If such companies collapse and liquidate, "untold numbers of future claimants will be left without recovery." Id. Meanwhile, present claimants want to be paid quickly and efficiently. "The Johns-Manville approach, now codified in § 524(g), seeks to use the broad equitable power of the bankruptcy court to resolve the dilemma in a way that is fair for both present and future asbestos claimants." Id. This history, the court found, "suggests that [§ 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III)] is not to be lightly discarded." Id. at 916.

In light of the statute's text, history, and design, the Ninth Circuit set out the following standard for determining when a plan, by virtue of its "specified contingencies," satisfies § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III):

"[S]pecified contingencies" . . . refers to contingencies regulated by the bankruptcy court to ensure that control is either a realistic possibility or a backstop to trust insufficiency. The plan can still "specify" what contingencies suffice, but those contingencies cannot be "shams" that allow control facially, but not in practice. To the extent Congress has provided an exception to the general rule that the trust should control the reorganized debtor, the overarching goal-that asbestos claimants get paid to the full possible extent-informs that exception.
Id. at 916. Applying this framework to the Original Plan, the court concluded that neither of the proposed contingencies satisfied the statute. Notably, as to the 11% warrant, the court held that "[a] mere right of the plan to purchase shares ordinarily will not suffice." Id. The court observed that if a trust is struggling to pay claims in the first place, it cannot be expected to purchase control of the reorganized debtor. "[S]uch a right leaves the trust in scarcely a better position than a third party . . . . This is especially true where, as here, the price the Trust would have to pay is fixed at roughly four times the current value of the equity." Id. The court offered some contrasting examples, remarking that it was "easy to imagine" what contingencies might satisfy the statute:
Most straightforwardly, a contingency that promised to transfer control to the trust in the event that it proved insufficient would clearly comply with this provision. A buyout right could be satisfactory, if that right placed the trust at an advantage such that it could use that right to claim value. Either of these would be consistent with the purpose of this section: to ensure the reorganized debtor continues to operate for the benefit of asbestos claimants.
Id. at 916 n. 9.

The court also found that the note-default condition failed to comply with the statute, but because that condition is not at issue in the Revised Plan, it need not be discussed further.

In sum, the Ninth Circuit in Plant III made clear that while a trust is not required to own a controlling portion of the reorganized debtor, the plan must at least enable the trust to obtain and exercise control in a way that "would meaningfully benefit the Trust." Id. at 917. If a contingency is illusory or burdensome, it will not ensure that the debtor continues to operate for the benefit of asbestos claimants.

C. The Revised Plan

Shortly following remand, the Plan Proponents proffered an amended plan that, in their view, passes muster under the Ninth Circuit's reading of the statute. The Revised Plan makes five changes regarding the Trust's ownership of Bayside. First, the warrant exercise price is significantly lower and provides actual "benefit" to the Trust. Under the Revised Plan, the Trust receives a warrant entitling it to purchase 11% of Bayside (bringing the Trust's ownership to 51%) for merely $1. The Original Plan, by contrast, required the Trust shell out $1,122,559 to exercise the warrant.

Second, the Revised Plan expressly authorizes the Trust to sell its shares to any party, subject to the Right of First Offer described below. The Original Plan did not expressly authorize the Trust to sell its shares to anyone other than Bayside or shareholders Shahram Ameli and Ali Badakhshan, who also serve as Bayside's managers.

Third, the Revised Plan includes a Right of First Offer ("ROFO") that requires the Trust follow certain procedures prior to selling its Bayside shares. If the Trust wishes to sell any of the shares, it must first offer them to Bayside, Ameli, and Badakhshan (the "ROFO holders"). If any one ROFO holder agrees to purchase the shares, and if the buyer and seller cannot subsequently agree on a price, the shares are to be sold at a price determined by "baseball" arbitration. If any ROFO holder elects to purchase the shares, the Trust is further obligated to finance the full amount of the purchase price through a fully amortized five-year loan at an interest rate of 3.75%. The loan must be secured by the shares purchased, and if the shares are bought by Bayside, such shares must be guaranteed by Ameli and Badakhshan.

In "baseball" arbitration, the buyer and seller each hire their own appraiser, who prepares a separate valuation report. The arbitrator then selects the report that she determines to be the more reasonable estimate of value, and adopts that value as the purchase price for the shares. See Bankruptcy Court Memorandum Re: Confirmation of Revised Plan Following Remand, No. 09-31347, ECF No. 2721 (Bankr. N.D. Cal. February 24, 2014) ("Plant IV").

Fourth, the Revised Plan provides the Trust with certain "put" rights, under which the Trust can require Bayside to repurchase those shares held by the Trust. If this right is exercised, and if the parties cannot agree on a sale price, the shares are valued via baseball arbitration as described above. Fifth, the Revised Plan does away with certain "call rights" from the Original Plan that benefitted Bayside and its managers. Specifically, under the Original Plan, Bayside, Ameli, and Badakhshan had the right to repurchase, at a predetermined price, any Bayside shares held by the Trust. Under the Revised Plan, by contrast, the Trust cannot be forced to sell its shares to Bayside, Ameli, Badakhshan, or anyone else.

The Proponents moved to confirm the Revised Plan. The Non-Settling Insurers objected, asserting two primary arguments: (1) that the plan still did not satisfy the control requirement of § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) and (2) that the plan did not satisfy the "feasibility" requirement of § 1129(a)(11). After the parties conducted additional limited discovery, the bankruptcy court held a two-day evidentiary hearing on the Proponents' motion to confirm the Revised Plan. On February 24, 2014, the court issued findings of fact and conclusions of law overruling the objections. See Plant IV. The Revised Plan was confirmed shortly thereafter. This appeal followed.

The Insurers do not contest on appeal whether the Revised Plan is feasible under § 1129(a)(11).

III. LEGAL STANDARD

When reviewing a bankruptcy court decision, the district court "functions as an appellate court" and "applies the same standards of review as a federal court of appeals." In re Crystal Properties, Ltd., L.P., 268 F.3d 743, 755 (9th Cir. 2001). While the bankruptcy court's conclusions of law are reviewed de novo, see In re Thorpe Insulation Co., 677 F.3d 869, 879 (9th Cir. 2012), the standard of review for its factual findings depend on whether the underlying proceeding is "core" or "non-core." When the bankruptcy court is engaged in a "core proceeding," its decision is final and its factual findings are reviewed for clear error. In re Harris, 590 F.3d 730, 736 (9th Cir. 2009). When the bankruptcy court adjudicates a "non-core" matter, it only has the power to make "proposed findings of fact and law" that a district court must review de novo. Id. at 736-37. Because confirmation of a § 524(g) reorganization plan is a "core" proceeding, see Plant III, 734 F.3d at 908, the bankruptcy court's findings of fact are reviewed for clear error.

IV. DISCUSSION

Focusing on a single provision of the Bankruptcy Code, this appeal argues that the Revised Plan still does not satisfy the statute's requirement that the trust "own, or by the exercise of rights granted under such plan would be entitled to own if specified contingencies occur, a majority of the voting shares" of the reorganized debtor. See 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III). Appellants contend the Revised Plan runs afoul of this requirement in two respects. First, it requires the Trust to make a costly initial investment in Bayside. In light of that investment, Appellants argue, the actual cost of control is extremely high. In Appellants' view, the Revised Plan cannot place any price on majority ownership, much less one that far exceeds the value of the underlying equity. Second, Appellants argue the ROFO prevents the Trust from selling its shares in Bayside "for appropriate value," and makes it "most likely" that Bayside or its principals will repurchase the stock on advantageous terms if the Trust, having exercised the warrant, chooses to sell the stock. (App. at 7:11).

A. Invoking the Warrant to Take Control

Appellants' first argument focuses on framing: what does it really "cost" the Trust to obtain control of Bayside, and does such cost preclude the Revised Plan from satisfying the control requirement? Under the Revised Plan, the Trust can exercise its 11% warrant for a mere $1-thereby all but erasing the $1,122,559 required by the Original Plan. In Appellants' view, though, it is pointless to view the warrant price in isolation. Instead, they urge, the court must consider the "true" price of majority ownership: $2,000,001, which accounts for the Trust's initial investment ($2,000,000 for 40% equity) and its warrant ($1 for an additional 11%). If the cost of majority ownership is framed accordingly, there is no dispute that the Trust must pay an over-market price to acquire eventual control of Bayside. The Plan Proponents, however, see it differently. In their view, for purposes of assessing whether the control requirement has been satisfied, it is irrelevant what the Trust paid for its first 40% of Bayside.

In its prior order confirming the Original Plan, the bankruptcy court concluded that 40% equity in Bayside was worth approximately $500,000.

Before addressing the merits of Appellant's first argument, a brief detour is warranted to explain how the Ninth Circuit in Plant III addressed a different provision of § 524(g). In their challenge to the Original Plan, the Insurers argued that by requiring the Trust to pay $2 million for 40% of Bayside, the Plan failed to satisfy § 524(g)'s requirement that the trust be "funded in whole or in part" by the securities of the reorganized debtor. See § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(II). Appellants had argued that by removing $2,000,000 in cash from the Trust in exchange for $500,000 worth of equity, the Trust is actually "de-funded" by Bayside. The Ninth Circuit disagreed. While the court acknowledged the Trust paid more than market value for the shares acquired at confirmation, it held that it was not necessary under the statute's funding requirement that the Trust receive any net value from the debtor through that transfer. See 734 F.3d at 914 ("[A]ll that this particular subsection must accomplish is to ensure that the Trust receives a stake, of some value, in the reorganized debtor."). The court further rejected Appellants' suggestion that the bankruptcy court be required to conduct an inquiry focused on whether the Trust obtained a "fair deal" in the transaction to acquire those securities, finding that such a requirement could be found elsewhere in the statute, like the requirements of good faith (11 U.S.C. § 1129(a)(3)) or the requirement that the court ensure the injunction is "fair and equitable" (11 U.S.C. § 524(g)(4)(B)(ii)). Id. The court further noted that, "as the bankruptcy court recognized, the Trust is getting a valuable asset from the debtor that dwarfs anything Bayside could provide-over one hundred million dollars in insurance settlement proceeds." Id. at 914-915.

In the present appeal, the Insurers object to the investment requirement on different statutory grounds, arguing the overall price of $2,000,001 cannot possibly satisfy the Ninth Circuit's interpretation of the control requirement found in § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III). In Appellants' view, the Ninth Circuit made clear that "the Trust should not be required to purchase this control; control is a statutory right" (App. at 17:7-8) (emphasis in original). Such a reading, however, is not consistent with the language of the Bankruptcy Code. While there is a "general rule" that the asbestos trust control the reorganized debtor, a plan can still pass muster under the statute if it contains "contingencies regulated by the bankruptcy court to ensure that control [of the debtor] is either a realistic possibility or a backstop to trust insufficiency." 734 F.3d at 916; 11 U.S.C. § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III). As the bankruptcy court observed, these "specified contingencies" only come into play when the trust does not acquire a majority of the debtor's voting shares upon confirmation. Because the trust is always required to own some securities of the debtor upon confirmation, see 734 F.3d at 914 (the "funding" requirement found in § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(II) ensures "that the Trust receives a stake, of some value, in the reorganized debtor"), the phrase "specified contingencies" plainly cannot refer to the terms upon which the trust acquired those shares in the first place. Rather, as the contingency model is an "exception" to the general rule of outright control upon confirmation, see id. at 916, "specified contingencies" must refer to the terms upon which the trust has the right to acquire additional shares after confirmation. Accordingly, the bankruptcy court was correct to conclude that under the plain meaning of the statute, the specified contingency in the Revised Plan is the payment of $1.

As the Ninth Circuit pointed out in its discussion of the funding requirement, there are other statutory mechanisms for ensuring the fairness of a plan requiring that the trust invest in the reorganized debtor. See 734 F.3d at 914. In so doing, the court did not mention § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III).

Specified contingencies "cannot be 'shams' that allow control facially, but not in practice." Id. Unlike the Original Plan, which required the Trust to exercise a $1,122,559 warrant in order to secure control of Bayside, there is no question that the Revised Plan allows control both facially and "in practice." See id. Although "[a] mere right of the plan to purchase shares ordinarily will not suffice," the proposed plan no longer creates a situation where the warrant "leaves the trust in scarcely a better position than a third party." See id. Indeed, the opposite is true. Whereas the Original Plan required the Trust to pay an over-market price to exercise the warrant, the Revised Plan places the Trust in a much better position than a third party seeking to acquire some portion of the debtor. Indeed, it is difficult to imagine a scenario where, by exercise of some right granted under the plan, it would be easier for the Trust to acquire post-confirmation control of Bayside.

As the bankruptcy court observed, this contingency is arguably less burdensome than one of the hypothetical contingencies posed by the Ninth Circuit in Plant III. Recall the court's remark that it is "easy to imagine" what contingencies might satisfy the control requirement: "Most straightforwardly, a contingency that promised to transfer control to the trust in the event that it proved insufficient would clearly comply with this provision." 734 F.3d at 916, n. 9. This dicta indicates a control-upon-trust-insufficiency contingency would satisfy the statute regardless of the terms under which the trust would acquire securities of the debtor upon confirmation. Assuming that sort of contingency would require some showing by the trust that it is unable to pay asbestos claims as contemplated by the plan, such a requirement would likely be more burdensome than the one proposed in the Revised Plan, under which the Trust need only pay a single dollar to gain majority control of the debtor's voting shares.

The $1 warrant satisfies the statute. By providing a specified contingency under which the Trust can take post-confirmation control of Bayside for a nominal sum, the Revised Plan ensures that control is far from illusory. Indeed, it is even more than a just a "realistic possibility." See 734 F.3d at 916. Following confirmation, the Trust faces virtually no impediment to its taking control of Bayside at its discretion.

B. The ROFO

Appellants further argue that the ROFO, a new feature of the Revised Plan, violates the control requirement by restricting the Trust's ability to sell, and thereby "claim value" in, its Bayside shares. See 734 F.3d at 916 n. 9 ("A buyout right could be satisfactory, if that right placed the trust at an advantage such that it could use that right to claim value."). "[T]he Trust cannot 'claim value' or 'backstop' the insufficiency of its assets," Appellants contend, "with stock that it cannot sell." (App. at 18:23-24).

The Insurers overstate the severity of the transfer restraints imposed by the ROFO. If the Trust wishes to sell any of its Bayside shares, it must first offer the shares to Bayside, Ameli, and Badakhshan. If any ROFO holder elects to buy but the parties cannot agree on a price, the shares are priced using a valuation method that is, according to a finding by the bankruptcy court, reasonable. See Plant IV Memo at 22. If the ROFO holders never agree to purchase in the first place, the Trust can then sell its shares to third parties. So while the ROFO precludes the Trust from taking its Bayside shares directly to the market, it cannot be said that the Trust "cannot sell" its Bayside shares.

While the Ninth Circuit emphasized that a buyout right must place the trust in a position to "claim value," nothing in Plant III indicates a § 524(g) trust must retain an unbridled right to sell its shares of the reorganized debtor however it sees fit. Nor does the text of the statute contain such a requirement. The Ninth Circuit made clear that § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) is about "control over the reorganized debtor's future operations." 734 F.3d at 915. As the bankruptcy court observed, control over such operations is derived "from holding a majority of voting shares, not from selling those shares." Plant IV, Memo at 18; see also 734 F.3d at 915 (statute's purpose signaled by use of "key" phrase "voting shares"). Accordingly, the bankruptcy court was correct to conclude that § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) does not bar a reorganization plan from imposing reasonable restraints on a trust's ability to transfer shares.

For their part, Appellees contend that any restraint on transferability, including an outright bar on a trust's ability to sell shares, is permissible under the statute. Because the Revised Plan does not include such a restriction, this order need not decide whether it would be permissible to do so.

Nor did the bankruptcy court err in assessing the reasonableness of the restrictions imposed by the ROFO. During the two-day evidentiary hearing on the Revised Plan, the court heard expert testimony from the Proponents and the Insurers regarding, among other things, the likely effect of the ROFO on the Trust's ability to sell its Bayside shares for fair value. Afterwards, the bankruptcy court issued a thorough Memorandum Opinion holding that the ROFO's restrictions are indeed reasonable.

The court's conclusion was grounded in several findings. For one, the court found that by using baseball arbitration, which by its nature encourages reasonable offers from both parties, the ROFO provides a reasonable means of valuing Bayside's shares. Although the Insurers' experts offered testimony to the contrary, the court found that testimony to be "wholly unpersuasive." Plant IV, Memo at 22. One of the Insurers' experts testified that the ROFO's arbitration valuation procedure was unreliable for numerous reasons, including that market transactions are "always more accurate than arbitration" and that "baseball arbitration is not the type commonly used in valuing companies." Id. at 17 (paraphrasing expert Neil Beaton). The court reasoned that the ROFO's valuation should not be measured only against a market transaction, however, "because the very nature of the restraints on transfer permitted in closely held corporations is to bar open-market transactions that could frustrate legitimate interests of other shareholders." Id. at 22.

Indeed, as the court observed, and as one of the Insurers' experts acknowledged, it is common for closely-held corporations to restrict the persons to whom shares can be transferred. Id. at 19; F. Hodge O'Neal, Restrictions on Transfer of Stock in Closely Held Corporations: Planning and Drafting, 65 Harv. L. Rev. 773 (1952) ("[S]hareholders in a closely held enterprise usually desire to retain the power to choose future associates."). From the shareholders' perspective, there is good reason for such restrictions-"[e]ach shareholder wants to be in a position to prevent outsiders from entering the business if he doubts their integrity or business judgment." Id. Looking to California law, the court observed that both the Corporations Code and California case law recognize a closely-held corporation's interest in restricting share transfers. See Cal Cop. Code § 204(b); 9 Witkin, Summary 10th (2005) Corp, § 129, p. 903 ("The usual restriction is designed to safeguard the membership of close corporations from entry of unacceptable outsiders, by requiring a first offering of the shares to existing stockholders or the corporation. It is not an unreasonable curtailment of the right of alienation or an unreasonable deprivation of the shareholder's substantial rights.").

Another of the Insurers' experts testified that the ROFO may prevent the Trust from seeking third-party offers before offering to sell its shares to the ROFO holders. The bankruptcy court disagreed, finding that the ROFO does not preclude such bids. Indeed, the court held that the Trust could solicit third-party bids and submit those bids as evidence of Bayside's value during baseball arbitration. Accordingly, even though baseball arbitration is a closed process between the Trust and the ROFO holder, the ROFO's valuation procedures are not necessarily insulated from market influences. The court accordingly found no reason why baseball arbitration would be harmful to the Trust.

The court further found that the ROFO does not merely burden the trust; it provides potential benefits, too. By ensuring that Bayside's managers will not be required to associate and share profits with third-party buyers, the ROFO "may" enhance the value of the Trust's shares:

While the ROFO might decrease the Trust's ability to sell the shares for their full value by restricting the persons to whom those shares may be sold, it may have the countervailing effect of increasing the value of those shares by eliciting greater efforts from Ameli and Badakhshan.
Plant IV, Memo at 20-21. In any event, the court concluded, it is far from clear that the Trust would be able to find a purchaser for its Bayside shares in the open market. Id. at 21. Although one of the Insurers' experts testified that there is an active market for partial interests in small companies generally, he did not testify that there is an effective market for partial interests in all companies including the likes of Bayside. As the bankruptcy court observed, Bayside's managers may well be the only persons interested in buying the Trust's shares. Accordingly, the court concluded, "it is far from certain that the ROFO materially diminishes the benefits of ownership of the shares." Id.

The Insurers contend the bankruptcy court erred by looking towards California law when assessing whether the ROFO's restraints are permissible. Their appeal, however, overstates the court's reliance on state law. The bankruptcy court's approval of the ROFO did not, as the Insurers contend, "fail[] to consider what federal law requires." (App. at 20:4). The court concluded first and foremost that § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) permits reasonable restraints on a trust's ability to transfer shares of the reorganized debtor. Only then did the court look to the law of corporations generally, and to California law in particular, to explain that it is common for closely-held corporations to restrain the transferability of company shares, a specific area on which federal law is silent. To be sure, there are important differences between (i) what is allowed under California corporations law and (ii) what is required under the Bankruptcy Code, but the court did not conflate these concepts. Rather, it concluded that despite the ROFO's restrictions on transfer-restrictions that are commonplace among closely-held corporations generally-the Revised Plan satisfies the control requirement because the ROFO creates benefits for the Trust while ensuring the Trust can sell its Bayside shares through a "reasonable" valuation process.

While the law of closely-held corporations protects the interests of a corporation's manager-shareholders, § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) serves to ensure that, among other things, when a trust does not retain majority control upon confirmation, it at least remains in a position to take control and "claim value." 734 F.3d at 916 n. 9. To the extent a trust chooses to claim value by selling the debtor's shares, there is some tension between the trust's interest in transferring the shares and the manager-shareholders' interest in retaining some backstop against the prospect of associating with unknown third-party buyers.
--------

Appellants also lodge a few factual objections, arguing the bankruptcy court committed clear error in its assessment of the ROFO's potential benefits. For one, Appellants dispute the court's conclusion that the ROFO "may" enhance the value of the Trust's shares by encouraging Bayside's managers to "continue to devote their skills and efforts to the company." See Plant IV, Memo at 20. As it stands, Ameli and Badakhshan already hold five-year employment contracts with Bayside offering significant yearly compensation plus bonuses tied to the company's net operating profit. Following the five-year term, they have the option of renewing for up to five additional one-year terms. Appellants argue that because of these "lucrative" employment agreements, the managers "[n]eed[]" no further encouragement to devote themselves to Bayside. (App. at 20:7, 15).

For a bankruptcy court's factual finding to be "clearly erroneous," it must be "illogical, implausible, or without support in the record." In re Retz, 606 F.3d 1189, 1196 (9th Cir. 2010). Although the Insurers offer support for their contention that Ameli and Badakhshan do not "need" more encouragement, their appeal falls far short of explaining why it was illogical, implausible, or without support for the bankruptcy court to find simply that the ROFO "may" enhance Bayside's value by incentivizing the managers' continued devotion. After all, the court's finding was couched in general terms; it did not conclude the ROFO would necessarily increase Bayside's value. Moreover, it is immaterial whether Bayside's managers "need" more encouragement. The bankruptcy court concluded only that the ROFO provides additional encouragement, thereby possibly making the company more valuable.

Appellants' second factual objection fares no better. The Insurers argue the bankruptcy court committed clear error by finding it "far from certain" that the Trust would locate a purchaser for its Bayside shares in the open market. Plant IV, Memo at 21. The court reasoned that shares of the company "might not be of much value to a third party" and that the Bayside managers "may be the only parties interested in buying the Trust's shares." Id. (emphasis added). Mr. Beaton, one of the Insurers' experts, posited that while the Bayside ROFO is "essentially meaningless from an economic standpoint" because Bayside's overall equity value is, at present, marginal, the company could become "considerably more valuable" in five or ten years if its operations were to improve "materially." (App. at 22 n. 18). Appellants take the position that while Bayside today may not be attractive to third-party buyers, it could be highly valuable in the future, at which point the ROFO's restrictions would pose a more palpable barrier to the Trust's ability to claim value. Again, however, the Insurers fall far short of explaining why the bankruptcy court's finding was unsupported, illogical, or implausible. The court concluded there was a lack of testimony showing the existence of an effective market for partial interests in all companies like Bayside. Again, the court's challenged factual finding was not couched in absolute language; the court found only that it is "far from certain" that the Trust would find a purchaser for its Bayside shares on the open market. Plant IV, Memo at 21. For purposes of establishing that the court committed "clear error," it is not enough that Appellants point to evidence in the record supporting a contrary outcome.

V. CONCLUSION

While § 524(g)(2)(B)(i)(III) "is about control over the reorganized debtor's future operations," see 734 F.3d at 915, the statute does not require that the trust retain an unfettered right to sell its shares in the organized debtor. Nor does the statute preclude an arrangement whereby the trust is required to invest in the reorganized debtor at confirmation, even at an over-market price. Because Appellants' claims of legal and factual error are without merit, the appeal is denied. IT IS SO ORDERED. Dated: 8/18/14

/s/_______

RICHARD SEEBORG

UNITED STATES DISTRICT JUDGE


Summaries of

Onebeacon Ins. Co. v. Plant Insulation Co.

UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA SAN FRANCISCO DIVISION
Aug 18, 2014
No. C 14-01200 RS (N.D. Cal. Aug. 18, 2014)
Case details for

Onebeacon Ins. Co. v. Plant Insulation Co.

Case Details

Full title:ONEBEACON INSURANCE COMPANY, et al. , Appellants, v. PLANT INSULATION CO.…

Court:UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT FOR THE NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA SAN FRANCISCO DIVISION

Date published: Aug 18, 2014

Citations

No. C 14-01200 RS (N.D. Cal. Aug. 18, 2014)