From Casetext: Smarter Legal Research

Netafim Irrigation, Inc. v. Jain Irrigation, Inc.

United States District Court, Eastern District of California
Jul 15, 2022
1:21-cv-00540-AWI-EPG (E.D. Cal. Jul. 15, 2022)

Opinion

1:21-cv-00540-AWI-EPG

07-15-2022

NETAFIM IRRIGATION, INC., Plaintiff, v. JAIN IRRIGATION, INC., JAIN DISTRIBUTION HOLDINGS, INC., IRRIGATION DESIGN & CONSTRUCTION, LLC, and AGRIVALLEY IRRIGATION, LLC, Defendants


ORDER ON DEFENDANTS' MOTION TO DISMISS PLAINTIFF'S FIRST AMENDED COMPLAINT

(Doc. No. 34)

This case involves an alleged anticompetitive acquisition involving competitors in the micro-irrigation industry. Presently before the Court is Defendants Jain Irrigation, Inc., Jain Distribution Holdings, Inc., Irrigation Design & Construction, LLC, and Agri-Valley Irrigation, LLC's Motion to Dismiss Plaintiff Netafim Irrigation, Inc.'s First Amended Complaint. Doc. No. 34. The First Amended Complaint (“FAC”) asserts causes of action under Section 1 of the Sherman Act, Section 7 of the Clayton Act, and the Lanham Act. Doc. No. 25. Having considered the parties' submissions, the Court will grant in part and deny in part Defendants' Motion.

BACKGROUND

This section summarizes allegations set forth in the FAC. See Doc. No. 25. Additionally, the Court takes judicial notice of the exhibit (Doc. No. 36-2) submitted with Defendants' motion to dismiss. See BMA LLC v. HDR Global Trading Ltd., 2021 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 169327, *8 n.4 (N.D. Cal. Sep. 7, 2021); Kim v. Shellpoint Partners, LLC, 2016 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 44144, *10 (S.D. Cal. Mar. 30, 2016).

Plaintiff and Defendants are involved in the micro-irrigation industry in Central California. Doc. No. 25, ¶ 2. Micro-irrigation is a comparatively cost-effective and sustainable form of irrigation that delivers water and nutrients directly to the root systems of crops. Id., ¶ 17. The micro-irrigation industry has three levels: (1) manufacturers that produce equipment for microirrigation systems; (2) local design firms that customize, install, and maintain micro-irrigation systems for growers; and (3) growers that purchase and use micro-irrigation systems on their farms. Id., ¶ 18. Growers do not purchase micro-irrigation equipment directly from manufacturers, but instead purchase it through local design firms. Id., ¶ 20. The services and expertise of local design firms are crucial to growers because improper irrigation risks harm to a grower's crop and livelihood and because micro-irrigation systems require substantial investments in equipment of as much as $1,000-$3,000 per acre. Id.

Manufacturers compete to supply micro-irrigation equipment through local design firms. Id., ¶ 19. To ensure that design firms are knowledgeable about the manufacturers' product lines and prices, manufacturers invest time and money in their relationships with the design firms. Id., ¶ 21. Manufacturers also often provide design firms with non-public pricing and individualized bids on large projects. Id. Notwithstanding these relationships, design firms have historically worked with multiple manufacturers to offer growers a wide selection of micro-irrigation equipment so that growers have a choice between competitive products and can select between them based on price and quality. Id., ¶ 22. This approach fosters competition between manufacturers to offer lower prices and higher quality so that design firms would carry their products and recommend them to growers. Id.

Plaintiff and the Jain entities are the two largest manufacturers in Central California. Id., ¶ 19. Other competing manufacturers include Rivulis, Eurodrip, Toro, Irritec, and Rain Bird. Id. In 2016, Plaintiff had approximately $65 million in sales in Central California. Id. Jain, on the other hand, had approximately $25 million in Central Valley sales in 2016. Id. Rivulis and Eurodrip, who was later acquired by Rivulis in 2017, had combined sales of approximately $20 million in Central California in 2016. Id. Toro, Irritec, and Rain Bird each had Central California sales in 2016 of approximately $15 million, $6 million, and $5 million, respectively. Id.

On May 16, 2017, Defendant Jain Distribution Holdings, Inc.-a sister company of Defendant Jain Irrigation, Inc.-acquired an 80% interest in Defendant Irrigation Design & Construction, LLC (“IDC”) and an 80% interest in Defendant Agri-Valley Irrigation, LLC (“AVI”). Id. Before these acquisitions, IDC and AVI were the largest local design firms in a number of markets in Central California. Id., ¶¶ 23, 24. IDC had stores farther north in Central California, such as in Dixon and Stockton, while AVI had stores farther south, such as in Fresno, Visalia, and Bakersfield. Id., ¶ 38. They had overlapping stores in the central part of the valley, such as in Dos Palos-Firebaugh. Id. Based on Plaintiff's experiences in and understanding of the micro-irrigation industry in Central California, IDC and AVI had the following estimated combined market shares in 2016 in the following geographic markets:

While the FAC explains that Jain Distribution is the holding company for IDC and AVI- and that both Jain Distribution and Jain Irrigation are wholly owned subsidiaries of Jain Irrigation Systems Limited, “an Indian multinational conglomerate” that has not itself been sued in this action-the FAC refers to Jain Irrigation and Jain Distribution collectively as “Jain.” See Doc. No. 25, ¶ 7. Defendants do not dispute this naming convention in their briefing. Thus, for purposes of this order, the Court will adopt that practice as well.

• Dos Palos-Firebaugh: Approximately 60-65%
• Patterson-Newman: Approximately 45%
• Stockton: Approximately 50%
Id., ¶ 25.

The FAC describes the Dos Palos-Firebaugh market as “no broader than the region bounded by Interstate 5 on the west, up to the Los Banos Waterfowl Management Area, San Luis National Wildlife Refuge, and Merced National Wildlife Refuge on the northwest, over to Chowchilla on the northeast, and down to Mendota on the south.” See Doc. No. 25, ¶ 67. Netafim had sales of about $3.1 million through IDC and AVI in 2016 and made about 50% of its sales through them in this market. Id., ¶ 68.

The FAC describes the Patterson-Newman market as “no broader than the region bounded by Interstate 5 on the west, up to Tracy on the northwest, to Waterford on the northeast, to Livingston on the east, and down toward Los Banos on the south.” See Doc. No. 25, ¶ 69. Netafim had total sales of about $2 million through IDC in 2016 and made about 99% of its sales in this market through IDC. Id., ¶ 70.

The FAC describes the Stockton market as “no broader than the area extending to Collierville in the north, the Sierra Nevada foothills and Escalon-Bellota Road on the east, the Stanislaus River on the southeast, and the California Delta on the west.” See Doc. No. 25, ¶ 71. Netafim had total sales of about $2.8 million through IDC in 2016 and made about 40% of its sales in this market through IDC. Id., ¶ 72.

Pre-acquisition, IDC and AVI carried and sold equipment from many manufacturers, including those of Plaintiff, Jain, Rivulis, Eurodrip, Toro, Irritec, and Rain Bird. Id., ¶¶ 26, 27. In 2016, IDC was Plaintiff's largest dealer in Central California, selling over $7.2 million of Plaintiff's products. Id., ¶ 29. AVI was also a large Netafim dealer, selling over $1.4 million in Plaintiff's products. Id. Netafim made substantial sales through IDC and AVI in previous years, and had invested in expanding its relationship with IDC and AVI. Id. IDC and AVI were also large dealers in 2016 for other manufacturers including Rivulis, Eurodrip, Toro, Irritec, and Rain Bird. Id., ¶ 30.

Post-acquisition, Plaintiff terminated its relationships with IDC and AVI because its products would allegedly be disfavored to Jain's products and because Plaintiff wished to avoid providing Jain with access to its competitively sensitive pricing and product information. Id., ¶ 33. Additionally, after the acquisition, IDC and AVI allegedly stopped offering the products of Rivulis, Eurodrip, Toro, Irritec, and Rain Bird to growers. Id., ¶ 34. Plaintiff attempted to make up for its loss of sales but was unable to replace IDC and AVI by selling more of its products through other design firms. Id., ¶ 42.

On March 29, 2021, Plaintiff filed the original Complaint in this Court seeking damages and equitable relief. Doc. No. 1. The Court later dismissed the Complaint's antitrust claims against Jain with leave to amend on the grounds that they failed to sufficiently plead a relevant geographic market and antitrust injuries. Doc. No. 20. On January 13, 2022, Plaintiff filed its FAC, alleging that it suffered millions of dollars in harm in three geographic markets: (1) Dos Palos-Firebaugh, (2) Patterson-Newman, and (3) Stockton. Doc. No. 25, ¶¶ 42, 65. Defendants thereafter filed their Motion to Dismiss the Antitrust Claims in the FAC on February 10, 2022. Doc. No. 34.

LEGAL STANDARD

Under Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 12(b)(6), a cause of action may be dismissed where a plaintiff fails “to state a claim upon which relief can be granted.” Fed.R.Civ.P. 12(b)(6). Dismissal under Rule 12(b)(6) may be based on the lack of a cognizable legal theory or on the absence of sufficient facts alleged under a cognizable legal theory. Godecke ex rel. United States v. Kinetic Concepts, Inc., 937 F.3d 1201, 1208 (9th Cir. 2019) (citing Balistreri v. Pacifica Police Dep't, 901 F.2d 696, 699 (9th Cir. 1990)). To survive a Rule 12(b)(6) motion for failure to allege sufficient facts, a complaint must include a “short and plain statement of the claim showing that the pleader is entitled to relief.” Fed.R.Civ.P. 8(a)(2). Compliance with this rule ensures that the defendant has “fair notice” of the claims against it. Williams v. Yamaha Motor Co., 851 F.3d 1015, 1025 (9th Cir. 2017) (citing Bell Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 555 (2007)). Under this standard, a complaint must contain sufficient factual matter to “state a claim to relief that is plausible on its face.” Irving Firemen's Relief & Ret. Fund v. Uber Techs., Inc., 998 F.3d 397, 403 (9th Cir. 2021) (quoting Twombly, 550 U.S. at 570). A claim has facial plausibility when the plaintiff pleads factual content that allows the court to draw the reasonable inference that the defendant is liable for the alleged misconduct. Id. (citing Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662, 678 (2009)).

In reviewing a complaint under Rule 12(b)(6), all allegations of material fact are taken as true and construed in the light most favorable to the nonmoving party. Benavidez v. Cty. of San Diego, 993 F.3d 1134, 1144 (9th Cir. 2021). But the Court is “not ‘required to accept as true allegations that contradict exhibits attached to the Complaint or matters properly subject to judicial notice, or allegations that are merely conclusory, unwarranted deductions of fact, or unreasonable inferences.'” Seven Arts Filmed Entm't, Ltd. v. Content Media Corp. PLC, 733 F.3d 1251, 1254 (9th Cir. 2013) (quoted source omitted). Complaints that offer no more than “labels and conclusions” or “a formulaic recitation of the elements of a cause of action will not do.” Benavidez, 993 F.3d at 1145 (citing Iqbal, 556 U.S. at 678). Rather, “[f]or a complaint to survive a motion to dismiss, the non-conclusory ‘factual content,' and reasonable inferences from that content, must be plausibly suggestive of a claim entitling the plaintiff to relief.” Hernandez v. City of San Jose, 897 F.3d 1125, 1132 (9th Cir. 2018) (citing Iqbal, 556 U.S. at 678).

If a motion to dismiss is granted, a “district court should grant leave to amend even if no request to amend the pleading was made, unless it determines that the pleading could not possibly be cured by the allegation of other facts.” Perez v. Mortg. Elec. Registration Sys., 959 F.3d 334, 340 (9th Cir. 2020) (citing Lopez v. Smith, 203 F.3d 1122, 1127 (9th Cir. 2000)).

DISCUSSION

I. Defendants' Motion to Dismiss

Defendants move to dismiss the FAC's first cause of action (Sherman Act, Section 1) and second cause of action (Clayton Act, Section 7) on the grounds that they fail to sufficiently allege a relevant market, market power, and antitrust injury. The Court will address each alleged ground for dismissal below in turn.

Defendants argue, without opposition by Plaintiff, that Plaintiff's antitrust claims under Section 1 of the Sherman Act and Section 7 of the Clayton Act are subject to the same antitrust injury, relevant market, and market power pleading requirements. Doc. No. 34-1 at 9-10. Ninth Circuit case law indicates that the standard for analyzing “relevant market” under Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act are generally the same as under Section 7 of the Clayton Act. See Newcal Indus. v. Ikon Office Sol., 513 F.3d 1038, 1044 n.3 (9th Cir. 2008) (“The ‘relevant market' and ‘market power' requirements apply identically under the two different sections of the [Sherman] Act, meaning that the requirements apply identically to [§ 1 and § 2 claims].”); Kaplan v. Burroughs Corp., 611 F.2d 286, 292 n.2 (9th Cir. 1979) (“Generally, principles of market definition applicable to cases arising under Sherman Two are also applicable to Sherman One actions, and to merger cases arising under § 7 of the Clayton Act.”); Greyhound Comput. Corp. v. Int'l Bus. Machs. Corp., 559 F.2d 488, 494 n.7 (9th Cir. 1977) (stating that a claim under § 7 of the Clayton Act “is equally applicable” to cases arising under § 2 of the Sherman Act). Additionally, courts in the Ninth Circuit have used the same standard to analyze “market power” for both Sherman Act Section 1 and Clayton Act Section 7 claims. See Intel Corp. v. Fortress Inv. Grp. LLC, 511 F.Supp.3d 1006, 1025 (N.D. Cal. 2021) (stating that “Plaintiffs' § 7 claims are subject to the same [market power] evidence analysis that applies in § 1 claims”); Med Vets, Inc. v. Vip Petcare Holdings, Inc., 2019 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 68099, *8 (N.D. Cal. Apr. 22, 2019) (“Where, as here, plaintiffs bring claims under Section 7 of the Clayton Act and Section 2 of the Sherman Act, they must allege a relevant market in which defendants have market power.”). Furthermore, “antitrust injury” is a necessary predicate for possessing the unique antitrust standing required for claims under the Sherman and Clayton Acts. Somers v. Apple, Inc., 729 F.3d 953, 963 (9th Cir. 2013); Glen Holly Ent., Inc. v. Tektronix Inc., 352 F.3d 367, 371 (9th Cir. 2003). Therefore, for purposes of this Order, the Court will use the same standards to analyze antitrust injury, relevant market, and market power for Plaintiff's Sherman Act Section 1 and Clayton Act Section 7 claims.

A. Relevant Market

Defendants' Arguments

Defendants argue that the alleged geographic markets (Dos Palos-Firebaugh, Patterson- Newman, and Stockton) are deficient because their boundaries were delineated not according to any alleged limiting principle, but rather to suit Plaintiff's litigation needs. Specifically, Defendants assert that the markets were gerrymandered to include certain areas and exclude others so that the resulting areas are ones in which AVI and IDC have high market shares. According to Defendants, these boundaries defy reality because they focus only on a subset of AVI and IDC's storefront locations and they fail to explain why some growers within the boundaries could not more conveniently purchase relevant products and services at locations outside the boundaries.

Plaintiff's Arguments

Plaintiff argues that the alleged markets are proper because their boundaries are based not on where Defendants are located but on where growers are located and where they can turn for the relevant products and services. According to Plaintiff, the FAC describes the population centers, illustrates the geographic features separating one market from another, and explains why growers located in these areas would not travel elsewhere for their purchases. Furthermore, Plaintiff argues that the details of any cross-border purchases and the contours of the geographic markets are factual inquiries that should be resolved on the merits rather than during the pleading stage.

Legal Standard

“A threshold step in any antitrust case is to accurately define the relevant market, which refers to ‘the area of effective competition.'” FTC v. Qualcomm Inc., 969 F.3d 974, 992 (9th Cir. 2020) (citing Ohio v. American Express Co., 138 S.Ct. 2274, 2285 (2018)). Setting the relevant market boundaries is a critical first step as it enables the court to assess issues regarding market share, the defendant's ability to lessen or destroy competition, and the alleged antitrust injury. Id.

To define a relevant market, the plaintiff must identify a geographic market. Hicks v. PGA Tour, Inc., 897 F.3d 1109, 1120 (9th Cir. 2018). The relevant geographic market is the “area of effective competition” where buyers can turn for alternate sources of supply if a seller attempted to exercise market power by increasing price or decreasing quality. Saint Alphonsus Med. Ctr. - Nampa, Inc. v. Saint Luke's Health Sys., 778 F.3d 775, 784 (9th Cir. 2015). A common method to determine the relevant geographic market is to find whether a hypothetical monopolist could impose a “small but significant nontransitory increase in price” (“SSNIP”) in the proposed market. Id. If enough consumers would respond to a SSNIP by purchasing the product from outside the proposed geographic market, making the SSNIP unprofitable, the proposed market definition is too narrow. Id.

A geographic market need not be alleged or proved with “scientific precision,” nor must it be defined “by metes and bounds as a surveyor would lay off a plot of ground.” United States v. Conn. Nat'l Bank, 418 U.S. 656, 669 (1974); United States v. Pabst Brewing Co., 384 U.S. 546, 549 (1966); see also FTC v. Lab. Corp. of Am., 2011 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 20354, *49 (C.D. Cal. Feb. 22, 2011). Rather, the complaint need only include sufficient information to present a relevant geographic market that is facially sustainable. Newcal Indus., Inc. v. Ikon Office Sol., 513 F.3d 1038, 1045 (9th Cir. 2008). Relevant market determinations are typically fact-intensive, with actual “inquiry into the ‘commercial realities' faced by consumers.” High Tech. Careers v. San Jose Mercury News, 996 F.2d 987, 990 (9th Cir. 1993) (quoted source omitted). This often enables market-defining allegations to survive scrutiny under Rule 12(b)(6). Newcal Indus., 513 F.3d at 1045.

Discussion

The original Complaint defined the relevant geographic markets as the “local geographic markets where growers demand design services and where design firms provide design services.” Doc. No. 1, ¶ 61. The Court rejected this definition because the phrase “local geographic markets” was amorphous and lacked limiting principles that would provide enough notice for the parties to be able to proceed with the case. The Court also rejected the definition to the extent it delineated the relevant geographic markets based on certain counties and zip codes. To cure these deficiencies, the FAC focuses on three geographic markets with delineated boundaries: (1) the Dos Palos-Firebaugh market, (2) the Patterson-Newman market, and (3) the Stockton market. Doc. No. 25, ¶ 65.

Upon review, the Court finds that compared to the original Complaint, the FAC defines the relevant geographic markets with considerably more concrete geographic terms which are not inherently implausible on their face. While the FAC lists all the localities where IDC and AVI had storefronts in Central California, it focuses on the three aforementioned markets in which IDC and AVI, for purposes of this lawsuit, had significant market shares and were relied on by Plaintiff. The FAC excluded some territories from these markets because they are comprised of uncultivated land, wildlife refuges, state parks, and mountain ranges. Additionally, the FAC relied in part on population areas designated by the U.S. Census to distinguish and demarcate these three markets. Although the Court has questions about the FAC's three-part division of the Central California region, the markets' “viability raises fact-intensive questions that cannot be resolved at this stage.” Pacific Steel Grp. v. Commer. Metals Co., 2022 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 75797, *28 (N.D. Cal. Apr. 26, 2022) (finding that alleged geographic market was not implausible on its face despite “the Court ha[ving] questions about this unusually narrow geographic market”); cf. Newcal Indus., 513 F.3d at 1045.

Defendants' main point of contention is that these three markets are not the “area of effective competition” because some growers within these markets could more easily turn for alternate sources of supply outside their respective markets. For example, Defendants point out that a grower in Los Banos, California (i.e., the Dos Palos-Firebaugh market) could simply purchase design services from competing design firms located in Newman, California (i.e., the Patterson-Newman market). Doc. No. 34-1 at 18. While Defendants' examples may be true to a certain extent, they are not dispositive. The geographic market inquiry used in the Ninth Circuit does not focus on whether all customers within the alleged area purchase solely from sellers within that area. Rather, the inquiry is whether “enough consumers would respond to a SSNIP by purchasing the product from outside the proposed geographic market.” Saint Alphonsus Med., 778 F.3d at 784 (emphasis added). Whether Defendants' hypotheticals are true and pervasive enough to defeat Plaintiff's geographic market allegations is a factual question not suited for resolution at the pleading stage. See High Tech. Careers, 996 F.2d at 990; Newcal Indus., 513 F.3d at 1045. At this stage of the litigation, the FAC alleges sufficient information to present a relevant geographic market that is facially sustainable. Newcal Indus., 513 F.3d at 1045.

B. Market Power

Defendants' Arguments

Defendants assert that the FAC fails to sufficiently allege market power to proceed with its antitrust claims. According to Defendants, the FAC does not provide any explicit examples of Defendants manipulating market-wide supply and pricing with their output. Additionally, Defendants argue that the allegation that AVI and IDC possess dominant market shares is deficient because it misconstrues their actual market shares and ignores Defendant Jain's market shares. Furthermore, Defendants contend that there are no “high barriers” that prevent potential competitors from entering the relevant markets. According to Defendants, the barriers to entry alleged in the FAC are simply costs that any competitor would incur when entering the relevant markets.

Plaintiff's Arguments

Plaintiff argues that the FAC sufficiently alleges Defendants' market power in that Defendants directly reduced choices for growers, excluded competitors, increased prices, lowered quality, and reduced output. Additionally, Plaintiff asserts that Defendant's “dominant market shares” have been sufficiently alleged and calculated based on its experiences in and understanding of the relevant markets and the relative size and importance of IDC and AVI therein. Furthermore, Plaintiff opines that the FAC sufficiently alleges market-entry barriers-i.e., that growers primarily rely on design firms they have used before, that growers are reluctant to switch to new design firms, and that design firms seeking to enter the relevant markets must invest in facilities and personnel, and develop relationships with, and expertise in the requirements of, local growers. According to Plaintiff, all the above direct and circumstantial evidence is sufficient to survive Defendants' motion to dismiss.

Legal Standard

Market power is the ability of a seller “to raise price and restrict output.” Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, 464 (1992); Rebel Oil Co. v. Atl. Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1434 (9th Cir. 1995). Market power can be proved through direct or circumstantial evidence. Optronic Techs., Inc. v. Ningbo Sunny Elec. Co., 20 F.4th 466, 484 (9th Cir. 2021). Direct evidence consists of proof of an injury to competition that a competitor with market power could inflict, such as evidence showing restricted output and supracompetitive prices, i.e., prices above competitive levels. Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1434. Circumstantial evidence, the more common type of proof, pertains to the structure of the market. Lucas Auto. Eng'g, Inc. v. Bridgestone/Firestone, Inc., 140 F.3d 1228, 1237 (9th Cir. 1998). To demonstrate market power circumstantially, a plaintiff must: (1) define the relevant market, (2) show that the defendant owns a dominant share of that market, and (3) show that there are significant barriers to entry and that existing competitors lack the capacity to increase their output in the short run. Optronic Techs., Inc., 20 F.4th at 484. Entry barriers include “additional long-run costs that were not incurred by incumbent firms but must be incurred by new entrants,” or “factors in the market that deter entry while permitting incumbent firms to earn monopoly returns.” Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1439 (citing L.A. Land Co. v. Brunswick Corp., 6 F.3d 1422, 1427-28 (9th Cir. 1993)). The main sources of entry barriers are: (1) legal license requirements; (2) control of an essential or superior resource; (3) entrenched buyer preferences for established brands; (4) capital market evaluations imposing higher capital costs on new entrants; and, in some situations, (5) economies of scale. Id. Similar to the relevant market definition, ascertaining market power is fact-intensive and case-specific; thus, market power allegations often survive scrutiny under Rule 12(b)(6). Eastman Kodak Co., 504 U.S. at 466-67; Newcal Indus., 513 F.3d at 1052. However, the allegations of market power must be sufficiently detailed “to raise a right to relief above the speculative level.” Rick-Mik Enters., Inc. v. Equilon Enters. LLC, 532 F.3d 963, 973 (9th Cir. 2008) (quoting Twombly, 550 U.S. at 555).

Discussion

Along with a relevant market definition, Plaintiff was required to plead that Defendants have power within that market. The FAC does not satisfy this requirement with either direct or circumstantial evidence.

1. Direct Evidence

With respect to direct evidence of market power, the Court previously noted that the original Complaint “[did] not directly allege that the acquisition choked output,” that “supra-competitive prices [were] not identified,” and that the complaint stated “in conclusory fashion” that the acquisition led to increased prices for micro-irrigation equipment and design services. Doc. No. 20 at 13-14. To address these concerns, the FAC alleges that Defendants denied growers that rely on AVI and IDC access to competitive products from Netafim and other manufacturers, such as Rivulis, Eurodrip, Toro, Irritec, and Rain Bird. Doc. No. 25, ¶¶ 33-35, 74. This resulted in: (1) “growers purchasing Jain products that were higher priced or lower quality than those they otherwise would have purchased,” and (2) “a market-wide increase in prices and decrease in quality” in those “markets where IDC and AVI had market power.” Id., ¶ 74. Furthermore, the FAC alleges that the market-wide output of micro-irrigation equipment in the relevant markets decreased as a result of Netafim and other micro-irrigation equipment suppliers being unable to sell through IDC and AVI. Id.

The Court finds that the FAC does not provide sufficient direct evidence of market power. Although the FAC alleges that Defendants' increased prices and reduced quality impacted “growers that relied on IDC and AVI for design services,” it does not allege any non-conclusory facts about growers' ability to find a better deal at other existing design firms, or about the prices and quality offered by other design firms, including those with whom Plaintiff had business relationships. See Dominick v. Collectors Universe, 2012 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 141950, *19 (C.D. Cal. Oct. 1, 2012) (finding no direct evidence of market power in part because the complaint made no comparison between the “higher prices” consumers were forced to pay with plaintiff and the prices offered by plaintiff's competitors). And despite the Court's earlier warning that “supra-competitive prices” were “not identified” in the original Complaint, Doc. No. 20 at 14, Plaintiff again does not identify supracompetitive prices in the FAC. See id. at *18-*19 (ruling that an allegation of “‘artificially high' prices cannot be equated to supracompetitive prices unless a plaintiff provides evidence to the contrary,” such as evidence that competitors are unable to charge similarly high prices); see also Sidibe v. Health, 4 F.Supp.3d 1160, 1180 (N.D. Cal. 2013) (dismissing complaint because “Plaintiffs' conclusory allegations [that defendant forced consumers to pay more] do not establish direct evidence of market power”). For example, while the FAC states that growers generally spend as much as “$1,000-$3,000 per acre” on microirrigation equipment, Doc. No. 25, ¶ 20, the FAC does not allege a higher dollar amount charged by Defendants per acre for post-acquisition Jain products. In fact, the FAC does not state the price of any single piece of micro-irrigation equipment or service at all.

The FAC's allegations of restricted output are also unavailing, and this deficiency alone may preclude a finding of direct evidence of market power. Forsyth v. Humana, Inc., 114 F.3d 1467, 1476 (9th Cir. 1997) (holding that with “no accompanying showing of restricted output,” plaintiff's allegation that defendant charged higher prices than competitors “failed to present direct evidence of market power”), overruled on other grounds by Lacey v. Maricopa County .693 F.3d 896 (9th Cir. 2012); Safeway Inc. v. Abbott Labs., 761 F.Supp.2d 874, 887 (N.D. Cal. 2011) (“[S]upracompetitive pricing, on its own, is not direct evidence of monopoly power.”). The FAC alleges that sales of non-Jain products through IDC and AVI decreased after the acquisition in 2017, resulting in “market-wide reduction in output of micro-irrigation equipment.” Doc. No. 25, ¶ 74. However, the FAC also alleges that Defendants engaged in a “major push” to sell Jain's products, implying that the decreased output of non-Jain products at IDC and AVI was accompanied by corresponding increased output of Jain products. The FAC also states that Plaintiff's “sales in Central California overall were increasing from 2016 to 2018,” suggesting that Plaintiff's overall output actually increased during and after the acquisition. Doc. No. 25, ¶ 42. While Plaintiff's overall sales might have been greater but for the acquisition, the FAC does not sufficiently address how Plaintiff's overall sales increased in the region amid Defendants' alleged restriction of market-wide output. Cf Humana Inc. v. Mallinckrodt Ard LLC, 2020 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 101378, *18-*19 (C.D. Cal. Mar. 9, 2020) (finding no direct evidence of market-wide restricted output at pleading stage because the record contained evidence that output of the product actually increased following the defendant's challenged conduct). Based on the FAC, it is unclear whether despite the parties' increased sales, the net market-wide output of micro-irrigation equipment declined as a result of Defendants' conduct. As written, the FAC does not sufficiently allege that Defendants restricted the market-wide output of micro-irrigation equipment. Forsyth, 114 F.3d at 1476; see also Humana, 2020 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 101378, at *18-*19 (finding no direct evidence of market power because the complaint failed to sufficiently allege evidence of restricted output); Dominick, 2012 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 141950, at *19 (dismissing complaint after finding no direct evidence of market power because the complaint failed to illustrate defendants' ability to affect the market-wide quantity of product by suppressing their own product). Stated differently, the FAC's alleged direct evidence of market power is not sufficiently detailed “to raise a right to relief above the speculative level.” Rick-Mik Enters., 532 F.3d at 973.

The Court recognizes that “a finding of actual harm to competition” may obviate the need for elaborate market analysis of reduction of output or predatory pricing. Oltz v. Saint Peter's Communty Hosp., 861 F.2d 1440, 1448 (9th Cir. 1988). However, as explained in a later section of this Order, the FAC does not sufficiently allege actual harm to competition.

2. Circumstantial Evidence

With respect to circumstantial evidence of market power, the issue is a closer call. As previously discussed, the FAC defines the relevant market as the market for micro-irrigation design services and equipment in (1) Dos Palos-Firebaugh, (2) Patterson-Newman, and (3) Stockton. Doc. No. 25, ¶¶ 59, 65. Defendants do not oppose the alleged product market in the FAC, and the Court found above that the geographic markets are sufficiently alleged. The FAC also alleges that in 2016 before the acquisition, IDC and AVI had about a 60-65% share in the Dos Palos-Firebaugh market, IDC had about a 45% share in the Patterson-Newman market, and IDC had about a 50% share in the Stockton market. Id., ¶ 76. While some courts have found percentages in these ranges to be substantial, “[a] mere showing of substantial or even dominant market share alone cannot establish market power.” Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1439. The plaintiff must also “show that new rivals are barred from entering the market and show that existing competitors lack the capacity to expand their output to challenge the predator's high price.” Id.; S.C. Innovations, Inc. v. Uber Techs., Inc., 434 F.Supp.3d 782, 794-95 (N.D. Cal. 2020); see also Pacific Steel Grp. v. Commercial Metals Co., 2021 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 97113, *16 (N.D. Cal. May 21, 2021); Dominick, 2012 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 179703, at *12-13.

The Ninth Circuit has held that a plaintiff need not plead market share with specificity. See Newcal Indus., 513 F.3d at 1045 (“There is no requirement that these elements of the antitrust claim be pled with specificity.”). “Courts have found rough estimates of market share sufficient at the pleading stage.” Alivecor, Inc. v. Apple Inc., 2022 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 49881, at *21 (N.D. Cal. Mar. 21, 2022) (collecting cases); see also Teradata Corp. v. SAP SE, 2018 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 209872, *55 (N.D. Cal. Dec. 12, 2018) (finding allegation that defendants “possess a market share that ranges, on information and belief, from 60% to 90%” sufficed to plead market power at the motion to dismiss stage). The Ninth Circuit has advised courts to be “wary of the numbers game of market percentage,” and instead consider relevant market factors including “market share, entry barriers and the capacity of existing competitors to expand output.” Pacific Steel Grp. v. Commercial Metals Co., 2021 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 97113, *16 (N.D. Cal. May 21, 2021). In light of these principles, the FAC's market share allegations based on Plaintiff's experience in, and understanding of, the relevant markets are sufficient at this stage in the litigation. While Defendants contend that the FAC's failure to provide current market shares makes it deficient, evidence of declining market shares in the present “may reflect an absence of market power, but it does not foreclose a finding of such power.” Oahu Gas Serv., Inc. v. Pac. Res., Inc., 838 F.2d 360, 366 (9th Cir. 1988) (citing Greyhound Comput., 559 F.2d at 496 n.18). The inquiry into Defendants' current market shares and whether they foreclose a finding of market power is better suited for resolution on the merits rather than during the pleading stage.

The Court finds that although some of the FAC's entry barrier allegations are plausible,the FAC does not provide sufficient evidence that “existing competitors lack[ed] the capacity to expand their output to challenge [Defendants'] high price.” Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1439; see also S.C. Innovations, 434 F.Supp.3d at 794-95 (finding no circumstantial evidence of market power at pleading stage in part because complaint did not sufficiently allege that competitor lacked ability to increase output in response to defendant's contraction); Optronic Techs., Inc. v. Ningbo Sunny Elec. Co., 2017 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 160238, *25 (N.D. Cal. Sep. 28, 2017) (same).

The FAC sufficiently alleges “entrenched buyer preferences for established brands” as an entry barrier. Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1439. Namely, the FAC alleges that new entrants do not have the “same relationships” that IDC, AVI, and other incumber design firms have with growers. This lack of established relationships is allegedly a dealbreaker because growers typically prefer existing design firms with expertise over their micro-irrigation systems and because switching to a new firm poses too high a risk to growers, “given the importance of proper irrigation to their crops and the substantial investments they make in their micro-irrigation systems.” Doc. No. 25, ¶ 78. Additionally, the FAC alleges that new entrants would have to “find local sales personnel that have or could develop relationships with local growers” and spend time persuading a grower who previously used IDC or AVI to switch to another design firm. Id. Taken together, these allegations plausibly allege entrenched grower preferences for incumbent design firms. See Sidense Corp. v. Kilopass Tech., Inc., 2015 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 162505, *22 (N.D. Cal. Dec. 2, 2015) (finding that plaintiff sufficiently alleged that it and defendant were the two significant producers in the relevant market, which allowed for a plausible inference that buyer preferences between the parties were entrenched); see also Aya Healthcare Servs. v. AMN Healthcare, Inc., 2018 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 102582, *64-*65 (S.D. Cal. June 19, 2018) (finding sufficient allegation of “entrenched buyer preferences for established brands” because plaintiffs alleged that defendants were highly recognized in the market and that potential entrants must develop a “sufficiently trusted brand” for consumers to hire them).

In Rebel Oil, the Ninth Circuit held that a defendant lacked market power despite its predatory pricing, because its competitors could and did expand their output in the relevant market. Id. at 1441-42. In reaching its decision, the Ninth Circuit provided the following guidance:

Market power cannot be inferred solely from the existence of entry barriers and a dominant market share. The ability to control output and prices - the essence of market power - depends largely on the ability of existing firms to quickly increase their own output in response to a contraction by the defendant. Competitors may not be able to increase output if there are barriers to expansion. One such barrier is lack of excess capacity. Excess capacity is the capacity of the rivals in a market to produce more than the market demands at a competitive price. If existing competitors are producing at full capacity, they may lack the ability to quickly expand supply and counteract a predatory's supracompetitive pricing. On the other hand, if rivals have idle plants and can quickly respond to any predator's attempt to raise prices above competitive levels, the predator will suffer an immediate loss of market share to competitors. In that instance, the predator does not have market power.
Id. at 1441 (internal citations omitted).

Here, the FAC does not allege that Plaintiff or any other competitor in the relevant markets produced at full capacity or lacked excess capacity when Defendants allegedly increased prices and reduced quality and output. See id. The FAC also does not allege that competitors other than Plaintiff, such as Rivulis, Eurodrip, Toro, Irritec, or Rain Bird, were unable to increase output through other existing design firms. See Optronic Techs., 2017 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 160238, at *25 (finding that although plaintiff identified other competitors in the supply and distribution markets, there were no corresponding statements in the complaint explaining why those participants could not increase their own output in response to a contraction by defendants).

The Court is also not persuaded by the FAC's allegations that competing design firms and manufacturers could not efficiently increase output by establishing new firms in new localities. The FAC itself states that IDC and AVI, even before the merger, were not deterred from expanding their store footprints to compete in new territories. Doc. No. 25, ¶¶ 25 n.4, 38. The FAC does not state why IDC and AVI could so easily expand, but other design firms could not.

Instead, the FAC alleges that Plaintiff attempted but was unable to make up for its loss of sales through IDC and AVI by using other design firms. Doc. No. 25, ¶ 42. The FAC also alleges that “[t]he impact of the acquisition on Netafim's sales illustrates that entry and expansion was insufficient to counteract the adverse effects of the acquisition.” Id., ¶ 78 (emphasis added). These allegations say nothing about the output capacity of other competitors and contradict the FAC's own statement that Plaintiff's overall sales in Central California increased from 2016 to 2018. Id., ¶ 42. The FAC does not sufficiently state how or why, after Defendants predatory behavior, Plaintiff allegedly could not increase its output but could increase its overall sales. Cf. PNY Techs., Inc. v. SanDisk Corp., 2012 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 55965, *30-*31 (N.D. Cal. Apr. 20, 2012) (holding that complaint did not show that existing competitors lacked the capacity to increase output because the complaint itself indicated that the plaintiff and other competitors actually increased output in response to the defendant's price increase). As written, the FAC does not sufficiently allege facts “above the speculative level” that existing competitors lacked the capacity to expand their output post-acquisition. Rick-Mik Enters., 532 F.3d at 973.

In sum, because the FAC does not sufficiently allege that Plaintiff and other incumbent competitors lacked the capacity post-merger to increase their output in the short run, the FAC does not provide sufficient circumstantial evidence that Defendants possessed market power. Further, the FAC also does not provide direct evidence of market power because it does not sufficiently allege that Defendants restricted market-wide output or imposed market-wide supracompetitive prices. Accordingly, the Court will dismiss Plaintiff's antitrust claims with leave to amend.

C. Antitrust Injury

Defendants' Arguments

Defendants argue that the FAC alleges many of the same deficient claims from the original Complaint. Specifically, Defendants contend that the FAC asserts the same conclusory allegations that the acquisition harmed Plaintiff and the competitive process itself-i.e., led to higher marketwide prices or diminished market-wide product quality for growers. Defendants also opine that the FAC fails to sufficiently allege that increased market-wide prices or reduced product quality are the cause of Plaintiff's own injury. Furthermore, Defendants argue that the FAC's allegations regarding the horizontal merger between AVI and IDC do not sufficiently state harm to competition because AVI and IDC were not competitors before the merger in two of the three alleged markets.

Plaintiff's Arguments

Plaintiff contends that the FAC sufficiently alleges an antitrust harm. Specifically, the FAC alleges that Plaintiff lost sales from growers who were not able to buy Plaintiff's products from AVI and IDC after the acquisition. The FAC also alleges harm to competition at large in that the merger had the anticompetitive effect of denying growers that rely on AVI and IDC access to micro-irrigation equipment manufactured by Defendants' competitors, including Plaintiff, Rivulis, Eurodrip, Toroc, Irritec, and Rain Bird. Plaintiff further argues that the acquisition harmed competition in that it eliminated actual and potential horizontal competition between AVI and IDC.

Legal Standard

“A plaintiff may only pursue an antitrust action if it can show antitrust injury, which is to say injury of the type the antitrust laws were intended to prevent and that flows from that which makes defendants' acts unlawful.” American Ad Mgmt., Inc. v. General Tel. Co., 190 F.3d 1051, 1055 (9th Cir. 1999) (citing Atlantic Richfield Co. v. USA Petroleum Co., 495 U.S. 328, 334 (1990)). “[A]ntitrust laws are only intended to preserve competition for the benefit of consumers.” Id. “Consumer welfare is maximized when economic resources are allocated to their best use . . ., and when consumers are assured competitive price and quality.” Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1433. Thus, “the antitrust laws are only concerned with acts that harm ‘allocative efficiency and raise[] the price of goods above their competitive level or diminish[] their quality.'” Pool Water Prods. v. Olin Corp., 258 F.3d 1024, 1034 (9th Cir. 2001) (quoting Rebel Oil, 51 F.3d at 1433). “[Limitation of consumer choice, in itself, does not amount to ‘antitrust injury.'” Somers v. Apple, Inc., 729 F.3d 953, 966 (9th Cir. 2013); see also Hirsh v. Martindale-Hubbell, Inc., 674 F.2d 1343, 1349 n.19 (9th Cir. 1982) (“[I]ntru[sion] upon consumers' freedom of choice by compelling the purchase of unwanted products . . . has been implicitly rejected by the Supreme Court as a sufficient independent basis for antitrust liability.”).

“The requirement that the alleged injury be related to anti-competitive behavior requires, as a corollary, that the injured party be a participant in the same market as the alleged malefactors.” Association of Wash. Pub. Hosp. Dists. v. Philip Morris, Inc., 241 F.3d 696, 704 (9th Cir. 2001) (citing Bhan v. NME Hosps., Inc., 772 F.2d 1467, 1470 (9th Cir. 1985)). “In other words, the party alleging the injury must be either a consumer of the alleged violator's goods or services or a competitor of the alleged violator in the restrained market.” Oregon Laborers-Employers Health & Welfare Tr. Fund v. Philip Morris, Inc., 185 F.3d 957, 966 (9th Cir. 1999) (citing Eagle v. Star-Kist Foods, Inc., 812 F.2d 538, 540 (9th Cir. 1987)). If the movant is a competitor, then it “must demonstrate injury to competition in the market as a whole, not merely injury to itself as a competitor.” Gorlick Distribution Ctrs., Ltd. Liab. Co. v. Car Sound Exhaust Sys., 723 F.3d 1019, 1024-25 (9th Cir. 2013). To plead injury to competition sufficiently to withstand a motion to dismiss, the “claimant must, at a minimum, sketch the outline of [the injury to competition] with allegations of supporting factual detail.” Brantley v. NBC Universal, Inc., 675 F.3d 1192, 1198 (9th Cir. 2012) (citing Les Shockley Racing, Inc. v. National Hot Rod Ass'n, 884 F.2d 504, 508 (9th Cir. 1989)). Such allegations must “raise a reasonable expectation that discovery will reveal evidence of' an injury to competition. Id. An allegation of a practice that may or may not injure competition is insufficient to “state a claim to relief that is plausible on its face.” Id. Discussion

The Court previously dismissed the original Complaint in part because it did not sufficiently allege that consumers (i.e., growers) and competing manufacturers suffered actual harm as a result of the merger. The Court stated that Plaintiff “fail[ed] to allege a single instance in which, as a result of the merger, a single grower was prevented from purchasing a single piece of micro-irrigation equipment,” and that “the only substantive allegation involving a postacquisition consumer describes a cantaloupe grower switching from Netafim to Jain, which if anything implies enhanced consumer welfare.” Doc. No. 20 at 18. Additionally, the Court stated that Plaintiff's references to reduced competition between design firms and higher costs for nonJain manufacturers to compete did not demonstrate harm to consumers. Id. at 18-19.

Upon review, the Court finds that the FAC does not cure the aforementioned deficiencies. In an attempt to cure the flaws of the original Complaint, the FAC alleges in relevant part that “post-acquisition, growers that relied on IDC and AVI no longer had a competitive choice of micro-irrigation products.” Doc. No. 25, ¶ 35. That is, “growers could no longer purchase products from Netafim or other leading suppliers such as Rivulis, Eurodrip, Toro, Irritec, and Rain Bird,” and this arrangement caused growers harm because they “could only purchase Jain products that were higher price or lower quality than what they otherwise would have purchased.” Id. Additionally, the FAC alleges that the acquisition harmed competition by eliminating “actual and potential competition” between IDC and AVI themselves, Id. at ¶ 39, and by decreasing Plaintiff's Central California sales by approximately $5 million in 2018. Id. at ¶ 42. The Court is not persuaded that these allegations cure the deficiencies of the original Complaint.

The FAC does not sufficiently sketch an outline of injury to competition with “allegations of supporting factual detail.” Brantley, 675 F.3d at 1198. Like the original Complaint, the FAC provides conclusory references to increased prices and reduced quality without factual allegations suggesting that growers suffered harm as a result of the merger. See GSI Tech. v. United Memories, Inc., 2014 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 54371, *9 (N.D. Cal. Apr. 18, 2014) (holding that plaintiff pleaded no facts, such as reduced output, rising prices or deteriorating quality, to demonstrate detrimental impact on the market). The FAC alleges that “growers that relied on IDC and AVI no longer had a competitive choice of micro-irrigation products” such as those from Plaintiff, Rivulis, Eurodrip, Toro, Irritec, and Rain Bird. However, “limitation of consumer choice, in itself, does not amount to ‘antitrust injury.'” Somers, 729 F.3d at 966. The FAC again provides a single substantive allegation describing a cantaloupe grower switching from Plaintiff to Jain, and states that this grower “suffered anticompetitive harm because it was unable to obtain the Netafim products that it preferred and had bought in the past, instead having to purchase Jain products that it chose not to purchase when competitive alternatives were available.” Doc. No. 25, ¶ 43. But this allegation again does not address the implication that the switch, if anything, enhanced consumer welfare, as the grower could have opted out for a different design firm selling non-Jain products but chose not to. The FAC does not contain sufficient factual details suggesting that the cantaloupe grower or others suffered higher costs and lower qualify from Defendant's products after the acquisition. See Zef Sci., Inc. v. Shimadzu Sci. Instruments, Inc., 2016 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 44123, *13 (S.D. Cal. Mar. 31, 2016) (dismissing the complaint's antitrust allegations as speculative because they did not provide any factual allegations to show how consumers were injured by the defendant's conduct but instead merely states legal conclusions of allegedly unlawful and anti-competitive conduct by defendant).

Moreover, while the FAC alleges injury to Plaintiff as a competitor, it does not sufficiently “demonstrate injury to competition in the market as a whole.” Gorlick Distribution Ctrs., 723 F.3d at 1024-25; see also Oregon Laborers, 185 F.3d at 966 (“The antitrust laws . . . were enacted for the protection of competition, not competitors.”); Siegler v. Sorrento Therapeutics, Inc., 2019 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 23779, *34-35 (S.D. Cal. Feb. 12, 2019) (holding that “[n]othing in Plaintiff's FAC alleges an injury to competition in general. Instead, all of her allegations focus on the impact of defendants' anti-competitive conduct-as it relates to her.”). The decrease in Plaintiff's market share, though substantial, is an affect to a competitor, not to competition. Pool Water Prods., 258 F.3d at 1036. Although the FAC alleges that Rivulis, Eurodrip, Toro, Irritec, and Rain Bird suffered harm as a result of IDC and AVI's removal of their products, the allegations are conclusory and do not state, like the FAC does for Plaintiff, that these competitors were unable to recoup any lost sales through their business relationships with other design firms.

Furthermore, the FAC's allegation that the merger harmed competition by eliminating potential competition between IDC and AVI is unavailing because an allegation of a practice that “may or may not injure competition is insufficient to ‘state a claim to relief that is plausible on its face.'” Brantley, 675 F.3d at 1198 (emphasis added). In two of the three alleged markets- Patterson-Newman and Stockton-the FAC admits that IDC and AVI were not head-to-head competitors but that they were likely to directly compete in the future. Doc. No. 25, ¶ 38. In the remaining market-Dos Palos-Firebaugh-the FAC alleges actual competition between IDC and AVI but does not provide sufficient factual details. These allegations do not sufficiently state that the merger harmed competition. Therefore, the Court will dismiss Plaintiff's antitrust claims with leave to amend.

ORDER

Accordingly, IT IS HEREBY ORDERED that:

1. Defendants' motion to dismiss the Complaint (Doc. No. 34) is GRANTED in part and DENIED in part as discussed above.

2. Plaintiff may file an amended complaint that is consistent with this order no later than twenty-one (21) days from service of this order;

3. If Plaintiff files an amended complaint, Defendants shall file a response within twenty-one (21) days of service of the amended complaint; and

4. The failure of Plaintiff to file a timely amended complaint will result in the withdrawal of leave to amend without further notice, and Defendants shall file an answer within twentyeight (28) days of service of this order.

IT IS SO ORDERED.


Summaries of

Netafim Irrigation, Inc. v. Jain Irrigation, Inc.

United States District Court, Eastern District of California
Jul 15, 2022
1:21-cv-00540-AWI-EPG (E.D. Cal. Jul. 15, 2022)
Case details for

Netafim Irrigation, Inc. v. Jain Irrigation, Inc.

Case Details

Full title:NETAFIM IRRIGATION, INC., Plaintiff, v. JAIN IRRIGATION, INC., JAIN…

Court:United States District Court, Eastern District of California

Date published: Jul 15, 2022

Citations

1:21-cv-00540-AWI-EPG (E.D. Cal. Jul. 15, 2022)